THE SOVIET UNION
Empire, Nation, and
System
Aron J. Katsenelinboigen
Transaction Publishers
New Brunswick (U.S.A.) & London
(U.K.)
Copyright ® 1990 by Transaction Publishers,
New Brunswick, New Jersey 08903
All rights reserved under International and Pan-American Copyright
Conventions. No part of this book may be reproduced or transmitted In
any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopy
recording, or any information storage and retrieval system, without prior
permission in writing from the publisher. All inquiries should be addressed
to Transaction Publishers, Rutgers—The State University, New Brunswick
New Jersey 08903.
Library of Congress Catalog Number: 89-28590
ISBN: 0-88738-332-7
Printed in the United States of America
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Katsenelinboigen, Aron.
The Soviet Union: empire, nation, and system / Aron J.
Katsenelinboigen.
p. cm.
ISBN 0-88738-332-7
1. Soviet Union—Politics and government—1917- 2. Soviet Union—
Economic conditions—1918- 1. Title.
DK266.K354 1990
320.947—dc20 89-28590
CIP
To my dearest friends
Helene and Herbert Levine
with love
Contents
List of Tables ix
Acknowledgments xi
Introduction xiii
BLOCK 1. THE SOVIET POLITICAL SYSTEM 1*
Part One: Russia's Fearsome Past, Stormy Present, and Murky
Future 3
1. Systemic Causes of the Present Crisis 5
2. A Multidimensional Approach to the Soviet Political System 29
3. Who Is Gorbachev? 65
Part Two: The Russian-Soviet Empire 91
4. Expansion of the Soviet Empire 93
5. The Military Imperial Orientation of Soviet Society 111
6. The Structure of the Second Imperial Circle, and How It Might 127
Change
Part Three: Nationalism 147
7. Russophilism 149
8. Some Notes on Soviet Anti-Semitism 169
9. The Soizhenitsyn Phenomenon 207
BLOCK II. THE SOVIET ECONOMIC SYSTEM 219
Part Four: Soviet Economic Mechanisms 221
10. General Observations on Soviet Economic Mechanisms 223
11. Inflation in the Soviet Union 255
12. Corruption in the Soviet Union 269
13 Multicolored Markets in the Soviet Economy 291
Part Five: Conflicting Trends In Soviet Economics In the Post-Stalinist Era 329
14. The Anatomy and Physiology of Soviet Economics 331
15. The Development of Mathematical Economics in the Soviet
Union in the Post-Stalinist Era 361
Part Six: Personalia 389
16. Jews in Soviet Economics 391
17. Nobel and Lenin Prize Laureate L. V. Kantorovich: The
Political Dilemma in Scientific Creativity 405
18. The Story of a Favorite Jew; Or, Aron Katsenelinboigen is a
Proud Name 425
Conclusion 449
Index 465
List of Tables
1.1 Soviet Steel Production, 1945-1988
1.2 Soviet Production of Metal-Cutting Machinery and
Tractors, 1945-1987
1.3 Two-Dimensional Culture Classification
1.4 Evaluation Matrix for the Situation in the Soviet Union
1.5 Some Characteristics of the Soviet System
6.1 The Population of Ideological Groups in the U.S.S.R.
6.2The Population of Major Moslem Regions of the U.S.S.R
in 1970 and 1979
6.3 The Population of the Baltic Regions in 1970 and 1979
11.1I Increase in Average Monthly Wages in the U.S.S.R.,
1950-1987
11.2 Ratio of Total Inventories (Retail, Wholesale, and
Industrial) to Deposits in Savings Banks
12.1 Connections between Mechanisms and the Signs of Reward:
12.2 Relations between Producers and Consumers
13.1 Basic Characteristics of the Colored Markets In the U.S.S.R.
First, I would like to express my gratitude to my sons, Grisha and
Sasha, for translating a large part of this book into English. In truth,
they were not mere translators, but detectives looking for meaning often
obscured by my Russian writing style. Parts of the book were translated
by Ann Kissin, William Scundrich, and Sharon Stefanowicz.
Special thanks go to Valery Chalidze, Boris Moisheson, Vladimir
Shiapentokh, and Alexander Yanov for many discussions concerning
the problems dealt with in the book. Vladimir Shiapentokh deserves an
additional "thank you" for regularly supplying me with articles from
Soviet periodicals. All these gentlemen have had a big influence on my
thinking, and I have internalized their insights to such an extent that by
now it is virtually impossible to draw a sharp line between some of their
thoughts and mine.
I am grateful to Gregory Grossman, Vladimir Kontorovich, Vladimir
Lefebvre, Herbert Levine, Pavel Litvinov, Dmitry Mikheev, Alexander
Radin, Alexander Riasanovsky, Vladimir Tremi, Valentin Turchin, and
Leo Zak, for their comments on some specific issues I touch upon in
the following pages.
For help in the long task of bringing my materials into book form, I
wish to thank Marvin Wachman, whose intervention got the process of
publication started, Katherine Steinberger, who went over the manu-
script and offered helpful suggestions, Frances Frei, Mary Kane, Vita
Kozlov and my wife Gena, whose
technical assistance was invaluable.
Introduction
I
emigrated to the United States from the Soviet Union sixteen years ago. Since
then I have been, and still am, mostly interested in the theory of
indeterministic systems and its applications to diverse areas of human
endeavor. But all along I have also kept a watchful eye on the events in the
U.S.S.R., which, incidentally, have provided me with a lot of raw data for my
theoretical ruminations.
Yet,
time being a limited resource, I somehow
had to justify to myself my preoccupation with the Soviet Union. Of
course, there were millions of people there, including my friends, suffering
from the lack of democratic freedoms and a falling standard of living. But the
situation in China and in many African countries was even worse, and better
familiarity with the U.S.S.R. was not enough to warrant a heightened interest
in it.
Of
course, the Soviet Union is a military superpower, and its military
preparations and actions cannot leave any one, especially someone who knows the
country well, indifferent to what goes on there. But the current strategic
situation is such that the Soviet Union stands alone against the entire democratic
world-not to mention the nondemocratic Chinese-and it may seem that the West
can safely ignore whatever the Soviet Union does, provided it is well-equipped
with both conventional and unconventional arms.
The decisive consideration that helped sustain
my attention to events in the U.S.S.R. had to do with the fact that the Soviet
Union is technologically one of the most advanced countries and with the fact
that it employs new technologies not only for military, but also for peaceful purposes. It is in
this regard that the Soviet system seems most threatening to its own people and
the outside world alike. New technologies, be they in atomic energy, genetic
engineering, or chemical manufacturing, are not an unmixed blessing for
consumers-they pack a punishing punch if used carelessly, and can end up
hurting people who live far away from the user country. In this sense they
are global technologies, and for
their proper utilization they require not only an investment in enviromental
protection, but also a sophisticated political and economic system. The Soviet
system, however, is such that it cannot, even with the most peaceful and
consumer-oriented policies on the part of the leadership, reliably avoid the
evils inherent in new technologies. The Chernobyl disaster brought all this out
with particular force.
The
evolution of Soviet society is thus not only an internal problem for Soviet
citizens debating the trade-offs between guns, on the one hand, and butter and
freedom, on the other; it concerns not only those who are troubled by the
unlimited power and ambitions of Soviet leadership in a period marked by the
rapid development of super-lethal weaponry, whose mere accumulation might bring
the world to the brink of catastrophe; it is, due to nonmilitary but dangerous new technologies, also
becoming a vital problem for people all over the earth.
I
have not only thought about these problems, but have tried to make my thoughts public in my writings: two full-length
books and a host of articles. The two books Studies in Soviet Economic
Planning and Soviet Economic Thought and Political Power in the
U.S.S.R. were brought out,
respectively by M. E. Sharp in 1978 and Pergamon Press in 1980. Most of my
subsequent articles on Soviet society came out in different English-language
publications in Great Britain, Japan, and, of course, the United States. Still,
a good part of what I have written on the subject has either not been published
at all, or has appeared only in Russian-language periodicals, primarily in the
magazines Vnutrennie Protivorechia and Vremia i My. As far as I know, none of these pieces has
been published in the Soviet Union, and only one of them, on Soviet
"multicolored" markets, was
circulated in the U.S.S.R. through samizdat
channels, in reverse translation from the English.
In
1988 these articles were brought together and issued in one book, in Russian,
by Chalidze Publications. The
book's readership in the West,
however, has perforce been quite limited. Because of my belief that it would be
of interest to broad segments of the English-speaking public, I decided to have
it published in that language, after appropriate updating and a drastic
reworking of the content to turn a loose collection of articles into a unified
structure. Undoubtedly, I have not been entirely successful in covering up the
evidence of my "crime," with the result that the kaleidoscopic nature
of the original material will inevitably reveal itself in one place or another.
One
common theme running through this publication is the contradictory nature of
the processes, past and present, taking place in the U.S.S.R., and the no less
contradictory nature of the opinions within the Soviet Union on how to deal
with them. Since each possible approach to dealing with these processes has its
own backers, some quite strong, it is impossible to make any firm predictions
concerning the Soviet Union's future. What I believe is possible is to
outline a general framework within
which future strategic choices will be made there. To wax cybernetic for a
moment, if Ivan the Terrible, Peter the Great, and Stalin wanted to see a
stable authoritarian Russian empire made up of stable elements, Alexander II
and Nickolas II were prepared to maintain the selfsame empire, but composed of
unstable elements. In my opinion, Gorbachev belongs to the latter group of
Russian rulers. But, of course, a complex stable structure does not have to
consist only of unstable elements - over time, some may become more stable,
others less so. It seems to me that, after a period of trials and errors,
Gorbachev has embarked on a policy of
balancing a greater stability of the inner core of the Russian empire with
considerable fluidity throughout its East European periphery.
The
book consists of six parts; the first three deal with the Soviet political
system, and the last three are devoted to the Soviet economy.
The
first part deals with some general trends in the development of Soviet society,
focusing on Gorbachev's efforts to replace the present ideocratic
system, that is, a one-dimensional system where all powers, including the
ideological one, are concentrated, with a multidimensional system. The
relevant dimensions, to name just a few, include pluralism, democracy proper
(not to be confused with ochlocracy, for democracy presupposes that competent and responsible people will
participate in decision-making), separation of powers, and openness. Building a
multidimensional society is a very complicated process: accelerated movement
along any one dimension may unhinge it from other dimensions and throw the
entire system back to its original one-dimensional state. Telescoping the
stages in a long process of pluralization seems particularly dangerous: a rapid
transition from the publication of ideas and their discussion by professional
groups, to the creation of popular
organizations and the staging of massive demonstrations in support of these ideas, could result in chaos when the other
dimensions, primarily the democratic dimension, lag far behind. Overcoming
chaos, as we know only too well, usually entails methods much more draconian
than those routinely employed by governments.
In
the second part of the book I deal with what I believe is the main impediment
to the creation of a multidimensional society in the Soviet Union, the empire.
Center stage is occupied by such topics as the impact of imperial interests on
the structure of the Soviet system, particularly on its authoritarian political
regime and a pervasive militarization of the economy. In discussing the latter point,
I stress not so much the direct outlays for the upkeep of the armed forces,
however large they are, as the general orientation of Soviet economy toward
quick conversion to military production. This factor, and the fact that the
branches of heavy industry that strengthen the
military potential are developed at the expense of the consumer, are, in
my opinion, responsible for the type of society that exists in the Soviet Union
and for the problems that it faces today: a deep exhaustion of human, natural,
and capital resources. It seems unlikely that the U.S.S.R. can meet its present
challenges without changing this tradition of militarism.
However,
the empire has been accumulated over the past seven hundred years-to be sure,
under different slogans-and it won't be easy for the Soviet leaders to give it
up. Hence, in the last chapter in this part of the book I tackle the following
question: Is the perestroika launched
by Gorbachev merely a breathing
spell before a new leap toward greater Russian military might, or does it
signify a change of tradition away from militarism and toward heavier
emphasis on a consumer economy? Given the prevailing strategic realities in the
world, such an economy is hardly compatible with the existence of the empire.
On the whole, I tend to believe (and this hypothesis receives a detailed
treatment in part 1 of the book) that Gorbachev's objective is not
democratization, but a preservation of an authoritarian imperial regime (a
constant of Russian history) through flexible means (on the model of Alexander II or Nicholas II).
In
the third part of the book I continue to elaborate on this thesis and apply it
to the ethnic problems in the U.S.S.R. I describe a spectrum of the strength of
ethnic sentiments ranging from cosmopolitanism to chauvinism, with
internationalism, patriotism, and nationalism being the intermediate forms.
Among other things, I discuss the prospects
for the victory of Russian nationalism and even chauvinism in a situation
characterized by imperial stagnation, shortages of consumer goods, an intended
increase in the prices of main food staples, the threatened layoffs of millions
of workers, and powerful separatist ethnic sentiments. Under these
circumstances, and given the still extant Russian imperial tradition, the
reactionaries could profit more than the liberals from Gorbachev's policy of
activizing the people through glasnost. This view is very different from the
conventional one, which welcomes glasnost
and only regrets that there is not yet enough of it.
The
Russian tradition and its real-life doppelganger, anti-Semitism, play a key
role in my argument, and I discuss them at length in this as well as in other
parts of the book. I try to show that anti-Semitism continued almost
uninterrupted throughout the Soviet period-only the rationalizations for it
occasionally changed. Because of poor compatability between the cultures of the
Russians and the Jews, it is quite possible that the Jewish problem in the
Soviet Union is insoluble.
In the second half of the book I take up
several problems concerning the Soviet economic system. The economy is an
organic part of the whole Soviet system that is responsible for plunging the
country into a crisis. During Gorbachev's rule, the economic situation has not
only failed to improve, but it has actually gotten worse, especially regarding
the supply of consumer goods. The foundations of the economic system have
remained virtually unchanged. A wide-ranging program of reforms aimed at a
rapid transition to a market economy, which Gorbachev announced soon after
coming to power, has so far proved infeasible.
First,
I offer a critical examination of the Soviet economic mechanism as a whole. I
also put forward a somewhat unconventional analysis of certain essential
features of the Soviet economy, namely, inflation, corruption, and multicolored
markets. Soviet authorities have long tried to hush up these phenomena,
believing dogmatically that they inhere only in a capitalist economy. They were
not supposed to exist, and hence did not exist in the Soviet Union.
Second, I assume that one of the key problems
of perestroika lies in the lack of well- thought-out alternative strategies of
Soviet economic development. That's why I want to examine the actual effect
that Soviet economic science has had on the evolution of the national economy,
and suggest some reasons for the conceptual poverty of Soviet economists.
Third,
I present a kind of a kiss-and-tell story of the history of Soviet economic
science. I was not only an observer, but an active participant in some of the
events to be described here.
These three broad questions are treated
respectively in parts four, five, and six. In
part four I also offer several
suggestions for improving the economic system. My major thesis is that what a
mature industrial Soviet economy needs to rid itself gradually of the
fetters of central planning is an indicative optimal plan, to be drawn up with
the help of modern mathematical methods. The shadow prices of such a plan can
serve as a first approximation to market prices. This, of course, does not mean
that I am against immediate decentralization in certain selected areas
of the Soviet economy, especially agriculture and trade.
Marshaling
specific arguments for my major thesis, I contrast the conventional
"plan-market" paradigm used
for analyzing Soviet economy with what I believe is a much richer paradigm of "vertical" and
"horizontal" mechanisms ( by "vertical" mechanisms I mean
those where there is subordination of some economic actors to others;
"horizontal" mechanisms imply the equality of actors). The trouble
with the plan-market dichotomy is that it prevents us from seeing a true
variety of organizational economic schemes. Vertical mechanisms, for example,
may entail not only planning, but also a Keynesian-type macromanagement, that is, governmental
interference in the market through built-in economic stabilizers.
In
this part, I look closely at one kind of vertical mechanism, which I call deconcentration,
and oppose it to decentralized, that is, horizontal mechanisms. A decentralized
business concern is an independent organization, financed by its owners. Under
deconcentration, hierarchical subordination is retained, but the upper levels
of the hierarchy do not interfere as much in the internal affairs of lower
levels, and the number of controlling parameters that the lower levels have to
comply with are reduced. Explicitly stated, the principle of deconcentration
(1) enables us to see how it is possible to construct flexible vertical mechanisms,
and (2) helps us to avoid the conceptual error of identifying the economic
categories of prices, money, and profits with capitalism. These categories are
economic invariants. Functionally equivalent, they differ only in the ways they
are formulated-by a central body in vertical mechanisms, or through local
interactions, in horizontal mechanisms. The truly schizophrenic nature of Soviet planning reveals itself in the fact
that, even with a small degree of deconcentration, the planners cannot
construct a price mechanism capable of equilibrating costs and the
centrally-determined production priorities.
Among horizontal mechanisms I distinguish
primarily between market and nonmarket mechanisms, the latter being represented
by universities, foundations, and the like. The market institutions are
designed to protect the interests of consumers, by endowing them with the power
to determine demand; the nonmarket institutions (not to be confused with
vertical mechanisms, for the nonmarket structures can be horizontal) aim at
securing the interests of producers, mainly the producers of new ideas. An
advanced dynamic economy needs both market and nonmarket institutions. Only
their mix will vary at different stages in the economic process, which range
from R and D to material production.
Further,
among the horizontal mechanisms I point out a special class of what I call
"centralized horizontal institutions." These are detailed and binding contracts for the production and
delivery of goods between equal actors who operate within the constraints of
aggregate parameters formulated by the center. Poor performance by this type of
horizontal institution is chiefly the result of various malfunctions within the
vertical institutions.
In
the fifth part of the book I look at various
proposals made by Soviet scholars for improving the country's economy (the
crisis in the economy was the chief reason behind Gorbachev's wide-ranging
reforms). My main concern in this part is with mathematical economics: I want
to show what illusions it engenders and what positive contribution it can make
toward improving the system.
The irony here is that professionally
sophisticated Soviet economists-who in effect undermine the foundations of
official economic science with their modern mathematical models-work on the
kinds of problems that tend to strengthen the centralized politico-economic
system; whereas their socially more progressive counterparts-the opponents of
centralized planning and the champions of more viable market mechanisms-operate
within a conceptually outdated framework of eighteenth century vintage, and
often confuse a Western market with a Middle-Eastern bazaar.
But
most Soviet economists are quite conservative both professionally and
politically. Cleaving to Marxist economic science, which so appeals to their
common sense, they want to preserve the present system, or, at best, give it a
minor face-lift.
With
such an intellectual base, it is a daunting task for the nation to attempt
a restructuring of its stagnant
economy. When the West faced a major crisis in the 1930s, it had Keynes, the
Cambridge school, and a good many economists who were sophisticated enough to
be able to understand and implement the revolutionary ideas of that school.
Individual
human dramas inevitably accompany and mirror great institutional struggles.
That is the reason why the sixth part of the book is devoted to a number of
Soviet scholars who have greatly influenced the evolution of the economic
science in the U.S.S.R. Pride of place here certainly belongs to Leonid
Vitalyevich Kantorovich, who was a mathematician, an economist, and a winner of
both the Nobel and Lenin prizes. In working on a seemingly small problem
concerning the optimal utilization of capacity at a plywood trust, this
extraordinary man solved the famous Monge problem. In an equally brilliant
demonstration of theoretical insight and, more significant, professional
courage, Kantorovich generalized the plywood trust problem to the national
economy as a whole: he represented the national economic model as an optimization problem, and saw in
the Lagrange multipliers-the parameters of the model to be treated by the then
new methods of linear programming-a most important economic category: price. An
iconoclast in science, Kantorovich was, however, a political and ideological
conformist-a fact largely responsible, in my view, for stymieing his further
scholarly progress. Such are the sad ironies of Soviet reality.
I
hope that the questions raised in this book will facilitate a better
understanding of the current events in the U.S.S.R. The polemical edge in my
work is doubtless somewhat blunted now, since glasnost made it possible for
Soviet media to delve deeper into certain issues that had received only
superficial treatment in the past, among them the problems of the roots of the
Stalinist tyranny, and the backwardness of socialism in comparison with
capitalism. The rate of thematic widening of glasnost has exceeded all my expectations: Marx and
Lenin have come in for criticism and lively discussions are being waged on
Soviet foreign policy. Just yesterday these subjects were sacred cows, and it seemed that they would
remain off-limits for the foreseeable future.
Glasnost notwithstanding, there are still issues (for example, the fate of
the empire, or Gorbachev's personality) that are politically so sensitive as to be virtually closed to debate. The
main point, however is that even those issues that are in principle open to
debate-the chances for the survival of pluralism, democracy, separation of
powers, and openness in a period of economic stagnation; the nature of
inflation and corruption; etc.-have received scarcely any serious critical
examination in the U.S.S.R. For too may years Soviet social scientists have
lagged far behind their Western counterparts, and it is bound to take at least
as long a time to close this gap as it took to open it.
I
believe that on the whole Western Sovietology is of a much higher intellectual
caliber than Soviet Sovietology. This is not only because scientists in the
West can speak freely without fear of their countries' internal security
forces. It is also because Western Sovietologists have been able to benefit from the broad conceptual progress
in the social sciences, from which the bulk of their Soviet colleagues have
until now been barred.
Still,
there is plenty of room for improvement, especially in terms of methodology, in
Western social sciences, too. This is true for both general and particular
problems, from the creation of mutidimensional political systems to the study
of inflation.
I
hope that the present volume, which brings together many of my writings on the
Soviet Union, will enable our Sovietologists to sharpen their methodological
tools and that it will draw them back once again to certain aspects of Soviet
life-past, present, and future-that, unfortunately, no longer cause scholarly
controversy. And I hope that the general reader will profit from an encounter
with a somewhat unconventional point of view.
1
Systemic Causes of the Present Crisis
Symptoms of a Crisis or Just a Slight
Cold?
The events in
the Soviet Union in the past fifteen years that preceded perestroika, give rise to the question,
" Are the negative phenomena visible there merely the result of short-term
fluctuations, or the symptoms of a deep-seated systemic crisis?" The
prevailing viewpoint, shared by Gorbachev, is that the country faces a crisis
situation.[1]
The decisive
sign of stagnation in the economy was the drop-off, dating from the late
1970's, in the growth rates in heavy industry. The main
element in the ideological justification of the Soviet system has always been
its ability to sustain a rapid growth in that sector, which was said to be the
key to the country's defense posture and to the prospective welfare of its
citizenry. To that end, everything else was sacrificed, including the service
sector, light industry, and agriculture. But when the growth rates, and
occasionally even the net output, in heavy industry began to decline, without
any concurrent improvement in the consumer sector, one could legitimately
start questioning the efficiency of the
Soviet economic mechanism as a whole.
Table 1.1
illustrates the situation with steel, which in the Soviet Union is considered a
leading economic indicator, similar to automobile manufacturing and housing
construction in the United States.
We can see
that the increase in steel production in the 1975-1980 and 1980-1985 periods
was only 25 to 30 percent of the increase in the preceding periods. Moreover,
toward the end of the 1975-1980 period even the net output declined, from 151,
453 thousand tons in 1978, to 149, 099 thousand tons in 1979, and 147, 941
thousand tons in 1980.[2] The production picked up somewhat in
subsequent years, but the growth rates have not changed substantially,
especially compared to those in the 1945-1975 period.
True, a
decreasing steel production could be a progressive phenomenon, signifying lower
steel consumption per unit of output due to its better quality, increased
sophistication in the manufacturing of steel products, or the appearance of
substitutes in the form of plastics and nonferrous metals.
I do not have
the figures on Soviet trends in steel consumption per unit of output, if for no
other reason than that most of them are still classified. Faute de mieux, we have to look at what has been happening with
steel-related products. For the sake of simplicity, I have chosen two of them,
metal-cutting machinery and tractors, which, thanks to their bearing on
defense, are of considerable importance for the Soviet leadership. The data in
Table 1.2 are presented in physical terms in order to factor out price fluctuations.
The downswing
in heavy industry has been so severe that the overall growth of the Soviet
GNP has ground to a virtual halt.
The troubled
economic situation becomes all the more significant if we realize that it was
preceded, and is now being accompanied, by a host of long-neglected and very
serious social problems.
In my view,
the present economic crisis in the U.S.S.R. is not a transitory aberration, but
the result of more than seventy years of exploitation by the socialist system.
A sharp drop in the overall rate of
industrial production has been accompanied by such phenomena as the exhaustion
of natural resources in inhabited regions, and increasing plant and equipment
obsolescence. Demographic problems constitute another symptom of a deep illness
of Soviet society: birthrates are falling, the death rate and infant mortality
are on the rise. The latter trend has little to do with the temporary problems
in infant care, but is rather the result of
a general degradation of the entire generation of newborns. The
incidence of mentally retarded children has also increased. These demographic
trends are linked to growing alcoholism and increased pollution (exacerbated by
the lack of appropriate safety equipment in industry), the prevention of which
requires significant capital expenditures.
One could cite
many other symptoms of a deep illness of Soviet society. Anomie and cynicism are a mass phenomenon.
Communist ideology provokes greater indifference than contempt. Heavy drinking
(according to a new version of the theory of historical materialism, a new
stage has emerged between socialism and communism : alcoholism) and ingrained
corruption in places high and low are universally tolerated.
Since the
symptoms I've enumerated have been widely discussed in both Western and Soviet
literature, there is no need for me to dwell on them here. The mere mention of
them is enough for a knowledgeable reader to conclude that there is a deep
crisis in the Soviet society. Next, I will try to examine several important
underlying reasons for this condition. I do not plan to prescribe radical
cures, but the reader is asked to excuse me if I sometimes give in to the
temptation to offer tentative advice.
Is The Soviet System Pathological?
What is the
role of socialism in bringing about the present crisis of Soviet society? This,
it seems to me, is a key question.
Before we
tackle it, let us first fix a few concepts: the concept of a healthy versus a
sick economic system, and, second, a normal versus a pathological economic
system. A healthy system is one in
which development corresponds to the wishes of the members of the society
(provided they have not been suppressed by the authorities); in a sick system,
development diverges from the wishes of the members of the society.
Respecting normality and pathology, Russell Ackoff, with whom Jamshid
Garajedaghi and I taught a course on the pathology of social systems at the
University of Pennsylvania, opined that a pathological system is distinguished
from a normal one by the fact that a pathological system cannot, using the
means at its disposal, maintain a normal regime and combat malfunctions. In other words, a system's illness is not an
indication that its condition is pathological.
Pathology arises when the system is incapable of handling the illness on
its own.
Now let us
apply Ackoff's idea to the analysis of the capitalist and socialist systems. Marxism, for example, considers the
capitalist system sick and pathological.
Its illnesses are plain to see: inflation, unemployment, crime,
prostitution, homelessness, poverty, etc.
According to Marxists, the pathology of the capitalist system is defined
by the fact that under capitalism
private property reigns, and each person pursues his own selfish
interests, which in turn engenders anarchy together with social, economic and
political illnesses.
Since under socialism property belongs to all
the people, and the system is guided by the State Plan in the interests of the
people, Marxism considers it to be normal and healthy.
Of course,
this view of the two systems is a radical one- in each, only pluses or minuses
are acknowledged. In a somewhat 'softer' version, Marxism would hold that the
ills of capitalism are stronger than
its healthy traits, and its pathology stronger than its normalcy. For socialism, the judgement would be
reversed.
This is
precisely the sort of view that reached its peak in the early 1930s. A deep
economic crisis that struck the developed capitalist nations; the World War I
which preceded it; the moral decline - these were all the results of internal
capitalist developments, in no way
attributable to communist intrigues. By
that time, the U.S.S.R. had embarked upon a large-scale industrialization. Soviet cities were growing, there was a
labor shortage, people were singing optimistic songs. The fact that this process was accompanied by the destruction of
a strong peasantry followed by an orgy of political trials against the
so-called 'enemies of the people,' was put down by Western liberals to 'growing
pains.' In other words, if the ills
from which the West was suffering appeared to the liberals to confirm a
pathological character of Western societies, the maladies of the Soviet system
were seen by them as mere growing pains, as minor sores on a normal body
politic.
Looking back,
it is easy to understand how difficult it must have been for Western liberal intellectuals to identify
precisely the pathological and normal cases. Exposes in an ever critical and
free Western press only strengthened the perception of an impending doom.
Because the Soviet press was under strict Party control, and the annihilation
of millions of people was carefully concealed, the liberals could take comfort
in the thought that the alleged brutalities were a fiction invented by the
enemies of the young Soviet regime.
With the
benefit of hindsight afforded by more than seventy years of Soviet rule, we can judge more clearly which system has proved to be normal and which pathological,
again, from the point of view of the Western liberal. The West did
manage to live through the most critical stage of its illness and recover, even though many sore spots still remain and cause a great deal of trouble. Soviet
society has entered a prolonged period of stagnation, and there is no
indication now that it will be able, even in the long run, to provide for the
development of a kind preferred by Westerners.
To be sure,
the picture is not all that simple. We cannot say that Soviet society lacks
features that most of its citizens find attractive. Arguably, many people, from
the most diverse strata, like the idea of the paternalistic state. The Soviet
people are also quite eager to see their standard of living increase, and they
resent the fact that the system can't provide it for them. At the same time,
the majority of Soviet people, or, more precisely, Russian people, would
strongly prefer an enhancement of their
country's military might to personal welfare, that is, they would be willing to
sacrifice individual material values and creature comforts for collective
military interests. It is not easy to evaluate the Soviet system in terms of
values shared by the Soviet people themselves, for it is hard to assign proper
weights to various components of people's preferences.
My guess is
that a Western person tends to see the Soviet system as pathological. For the
majority of Soviet citizens, maybe even an overwhelming majority, their system,
though sickly, is normal and not pathological. Soviet people by and large tend
to believe that their system can
overcome the current problems and fulfill
their aspirations, with the important proviso that to do so it needs a
good leader. Only a small minority of active people, who cherish the ideal of
independent initiative, can be said to reject the system. Their sentiments are
perhaps shared at the top by a fairly large number of leaders who think that
the system cannot reliably secure the enhancement of state power, which is a
necessary condition for the enhancement of the leaders' personal prestige. But
the majority of people - leaders and citizens alike - are convinced that a
Soviet-type system shored up by Stalinist controls ( but without Stalinist
excesses ) is more attuned to Russian culture.
At the risk of
gross simplification, I would hazard a two-dimensional classification of
cultures premised on (1) the nation's craving for leadership and (2) its
ability to work without compulsion. Allowing only binary choices in each
dimension ( and adding illustrative examples for each type of culture ),
produces the matrix shown in table 1.3.
What is it in
the mentality of the Russians that makes them opt for authoritarianism? That
Russians are a capable people can be amply demonstrated. To cite but one fact
among many, recall the rapid Soviet industrialization of the 1930s, which
brought forth a huge professional cadre of Russian engineers and workers able
to operate and maintain sophisticated equipment. At the same time, it is
well-known that the Russians are much prone to drinking, besotted debauchery,
and irresponsibility. Apparently, the Russians themselves are aware of their
character defects, and hence crave a strong leader who can save them from
harmful temptations and channel their energies toward constructive ends; among
those ends a militarily powerful and independent Russia capable of repulsing
any foreign invader occupies pride of place. The historical record of Russian arms
is deeply rooted in the consciousness of the people who have been willing to
sacrifice so much in both victory and defeat.
I believe that
it is the culture of the nation, and especially its way of resolving the
tension between the civil rights and socioeconomic rights, that ultimately
determines its choice between capitalism and socialism.
What Do Soviet People Prefer More -
Civil Rights or Socioeconomic Rights?
There is much
in Russian culture that is in keeping with socialist ideals. This is not to say
that all Russians subscribe to these
ideals. Far from it. Only that the champions of a non-socialist orientation in
Russia have never constituted that critical mass which is needed to replace the
dominant value system.
There are many
preconditions for capitalism, one of which is the presence of a critical mass
of people with a certain value system. A key element in this system is the
relationship between man and society. The crux of the matter can be expressed
as follows : Does the individual exist for the society, or the society for the
individual?
The Protestant
ethic, which has nourished the development of some Western countries, and especially that of the United States, is
largely premised on the notion that the society serves the individual. This squares
rather well with capitalism's cult of the individual.[3] On the other hand, those Christian
countries that are Catholic or Orthodox tend to subordinate individual
interests to collective ones, and
exhibit a fairly strong proclivity for various kinds of socialism, including
the corporatist one, that is, fascism. Social structures are by no means
uniquely determined by religion, but it may be surmised that the primacy of the
individual over the collectivity is a sine qua non of any stable capitalist order.
The Russians
tend to operate on the assumption that man is subordinate to society.[4]
When the
Russophiles argue against the West, that is, the Protestant capitalist West,
they stress the organic unity of Russian society, in which the individual is
but a subservient part of the whole body politic.
Where one
stands in relation to the man-society dichotomy has many important
consequences. Specifically, it affects one's attitude toward civil and socioeconomic rights.[5]
Principally,
civil rights are the birthrights that man does not want anyone to take away
from him; socioeconomic rights are those rights that man insists be given to
him.
In the former
case, the individual wants to preserve his right to speak freely, to choose his
political leaders, to decide independently where to live and to work. In the
latter case, the individual wants someone else to feed, clothe, and, educate him, provide him with housing and
medical care, compensate him for his mistakes, and instruct him in the best
life to lead.
Each kind of
right entails its own form of responsibility. With civil rights, man assumes a
personal responsibility for the consequences of his actions, including negative
ones. With socioeconomic rights, man has to give up his freedom to satisfy the
demands of the provider, for how else can the provider be sure of a proper
disposition of his largess? It is not inconceivable for a provider to be
motivated solely by philanthropic considerations, but, alas, the charitable
impulse is always in short supply, and it runs out particularly fast when the
demand for it is strong. When too many people desire socioeconomic rights and
personal security, they have to ask the collectives to effect redistribution
coercively. In prerevolutionary Russia, these collectives were peasant
communities; in the present-day U.S.S.R., it is the whole society.
In a word, the
"gimme" types have to be prepared to suffer authoritarianism and to
part with their freedom. The hope for sustained, non-coercive charity is
unrealistic. The ideal of a "gimme" person is a strict but
fair-minded leader who generously dispenses all sorts of goodies to the people.
The leader,
however, is after all only a mortal human being, with interests of his own. His
interests may sometimes coincide with those of the majority of the people, but
they may also diverge. In any event, an authoritarian regime is poorly suited
to effect sustained technological progress or the multiplicity of
organizational changes that such a progress requires. An authoritarian regime
does much better at setting specific, clear-cut goals, and gearing up the
entire country toward the realization of these goals. Unfortunately, this
pattern of development leads in fairly short order to the exhaustion of the
country and, most likely, to prolonged stagnation.
The leader of
an authoritarian state has a hard time securing his prestige by a marked and
steady growth in his subjects' material welfare. For him, a more reliable and
effective path to personal glory runs through outward expansionism. This path is all the more tempting the firmer the
leader's grip on the country. His grip is the firmest if he is a hereditary
ruler or a liberator. Despairing of any quick results along the road of
internal betterment, he pins his hopes on creating a new movement, an
expansionist ideology of foreign conquest and subjugation.
This policy
enables the leader to satisfy not only his personal ambitions, but also, to a
degree, the interests of his subjects. Economic and social resentments are
drowned in the roar of patriots proud of their country's military might. The
populace acquires a feeling of national superiority, and also a sense of
greater security, for a larger and stronger country is less threatened by
foreign invasions. For a country like Russia, itself a victim of frequent
outside attacks and prolonged occupation, this feeling is especially acute.
Moreover, a
policy of expansionism affords the leader a certain safety valve: he can now
shunt the active part of the population into the newly occupied territories by
granting them land and governmental positions. The potential foci of opposition
are thus removed from the mother country, and become the regime's bulwark in
the colonies.
The circle is
completed: an authoritarian regime driven by expansionism harmonizes the
interests of leaders and of a populace
composed largely of "gimme" types.
The Soviet
experience shows, though, that the recipient may soon discover how self-serving
and tightfisted his 'benefactor' really is. With this new awareness, he is
likely to switch to the opposite extreme, and instead of praising the
dispenser, he takes to lambasting him. The aggrieved party, cheated by the
benefactor, the recipient now feels no compunction about gypping him too. There
is a ground-swell of immorality and corruption, with most people being
convinced that swindling the government is a noble and heroic activity, shunned
only by imbeciles.
Such, on the
whole, has been the history of the Muscovy Russian state for the past seven
hundred years. And today, too, we can expect conflict between civil and socioeconomic rights in Russia. That's
why Russian history must be studied thoroughly. I totally subscribe to the
proposition that a country ashamed of its past has no future. In judging the past, however,
it is not only the end- result of the historical process, but also the process
itself that are important.[6]
A leader who
champions civil rights will defend his position by general appeals to the
requirements of technological progress and economic growth. Some Soviet officials
have repeatedly stressed lately that, without civil rights, Russia will not
overcome its present economic backwardness, and may even lose its superpower
status and slide down to the rank of a Third ( or, as someone remarked
pointedly, even a Fifth) World country. Undoubtedly, technological progress is
important for maintaining superpower
status. Certainly, a country that respects civil rights enjoys better prospects
for technological advancement and increased efficiency. Yet, without going into
a theoretical discussion of the correlation of civil rights and growing
prosperity, I can only say that a supporter of human liberties in the U.S.S.R.
would be hard put to parry the
arguments of a Russian chauvinist and
backer of authoritarianism. To the former's contention that civil rights
are needed, if only to keep Russia itself militarily strong, the latter may
reply in something like the following manner:
" Why are
you trying to scare us with your talk of military backwardness if we don't
democratize?! Look at the situation Russia was in at the end of the seventeenth
and the beginning of the eighteenth century. It was a backward country,
repeatedly beaten by Sweden, which at that time was one of the most influential
powers in the world. The Swedish Empire included Finland and the southern
Baltic littoral; its expansionist ambitions were enormous. But then came Peter
the Great, who rapidly industrialized Russia, built very powerful land and sea
forces, smashed the Swedes, and annexed the long-coveted Baltic coast to
Russia. Where is your vaunted Swedish Empire now, who remembers it? The Empire
created by Peter, on the other hand, has not only been preserved, but also much
augmented.
"A
similar situation obtained in the 1920s. After World War I, Russia was again a
backward country unable to produce modern weaponry domestically. Stalin changed
all that in very short order. The power
that he helped create was sufficient to rout Hitler and to expand the country
both east and west. Russia's might, and the ability to produce modern weapons,
did not stop increasing after the war, either. Many in the West believed that
it would take us twenty years to make our own A-bomb. In the event, it took us
only three years: the first Soviet atomic bomb was successfully tested in 1948.
In August 1953 we had a successful aerial test of the H-bomb. True, we did not
then have a powerful strategic air
force to take the bomb to the target; but we were already close to having a new
means of delivery, the missiles. And when, in 1957, we had our first Sputnik
shot, the West was shocked, for it lacked anything like it.
"All this
was done largely under an authoritarian Stalinist regime. Therefore, we think
that the Russian people have a unique national character, more in tune with
such a regime, which even today hasn't lost its capacity to preserve and
multiply Russia's might. As to the low standard of living, and even human
casualties, these are not as important to us as is Russia's power. On this
point we are very different from the West. We have been prepared to suffer in
the past, and will be ready to suffer again in the future, for a great cause of
Russia's glory, provided the country is ruled by a strong leader capable of
channeling its power in the right direction."
What is Socialism?
Thus, civil
and socioeconomic rights can clash: to secure civil rights, it may be necessary
at times to sacrifice socioeconomic rights, and vice versa. But regardless of
people's preferences for one or another set of rights, they all want to see an increase
in their overall quality of life. Moreover, people belonging to an extraverted
culture ( and both Westerners and Russians are extraverts) also want to see an
increase in their standard of living, which is an important component of life's quality.
The demands
for a higher quality of life may come into conflict with the demands for a
higher standard of living. For example, the existence of economic inequality
may lower a quality of life of the economically disadvantaged. The socialist
principle "From each according to his abilities, to each according to his
work" is a quintessential expression of the idea of equal distribution.
Indeed, if distribution were to be organized in accordance with just the first
part of the principle, considerable inequality would follow as a result of
differences in people's abilities. The same would be true if only the second
part of the principle were to be used as a criterion for distribution: the work
that people perform differs not only in terms of volume, but also in terms of
content, that is, in contribution, however defined, that it makes to the
national product. What the socialist principle as a whole asserts is that the ratio
of individual abilities to individual output, and hence the renumeration, be
equal for all actors - more gifted people are expected to produce more
than people with lesser abilities.
We should also
note that the socialist principle of distribution has no room for a category of savings-generated income
resulting from deferred consumption.[7]
An emphasis on
economic equality, on the other hand, may deprive people of incentives to
produce, and, more importantly, prevent the emergence of those groups of
individuals who, having accumulated considerable wealth, can perform
decentralized investments into the new and risky ventures in the arts,
sciences, and engineering projects. In other words, an economic inequality may
prove a necessary condition for welfare growth.
Obviously, equal distribution is easiest if the society
is infinitely rich and can secure for all its members an equally high level of
welfare. A poor society that puts a premium on socioeconomic rights can attain
equality of distribution only at a low level of satisfaction of its members'
wants. That the poor's commitment to egalitarianism might clash with the need
to preserve skilled professionals should, however, also be taken into account.
There are some
well-known theories which purport to reconcile the conflict between civil and
socioeconomic rights. Once harmonized, they are alleged to guarantee a
simultaneous growth of welfare and
quality of life. It is such theories that I choose to call socialistic.[8]
The ideology
of socialism challenged the society based on the primacy of civil rights, for
the latter, even though it may promote growth of living standards, does not
guarantee socioeconomic rights.
If we assume
that the goal of socialism, as here defined, can never be completely attained,
it becomes, in the terminology of Russell Ackoff, an ideal.[9] The fact that ideals are unattainable
does not however preclude a successful movement towards them.
Sweden has
probably come closest to the ideal of socialism, and the Swedish experience has
of late been studied rather closely by Soviet liberals. But the Swedish model,
too, is fraught with considerable dangers. An emphasis on equality and security
has produced a highly progressive income tax schedule, cut into the number of
rich people, and sharply curtailed the role of individual capital investment.
Therefore, one should not feel surprised at the not-too-distant electoral
defeats of the formerly unchallengeable Swedish Social-Democratic party.
Similar phenomena can be observed in Norway and Britain. All this reminds us
that we have to exercise extreme care when dealing with ideals, and never lose
sight of the fact that ideals are situations to be striven for, not feasible
objectives. Moreover, the attempt to reach an ideal by accentuating only some
of its dimensions can result in losses along other dimensions, the slowing down
of the motive forces of development, and eventually even in the deterioration
of the ideal in toto.[10]
The ordered
pairs of rights we have discussed so far represent only the starkers choices;
various mixed strategies and compromises between them are also possible, as the
experience of the United States and some Western European countries (e.g. the
FRG, Italy) so amply demonstrates. The aim of these compromises was not to
provide all socioeconomic rights to everybody, but some of these rights (in the
US, a minimum hourly wage, social security) to those individuals who have
temporarily fallen on hard times (in the US, the system of Medicaid and
Medicare). The inequality in these countries has also shrunk thanks to the
introduction of a progressive income tax.
Whatever the possible
combinations between the civil and socioeconomic rights, on the one hand, and
welfare and quality of life, on the other, the key terms in my definition of
socialism ( in a descending order of importance) are security, growth of living
standards, growth of quality of life, and civil rights.
The parameters
here selected make the designation of various countries as socialist somewhat
less stringent than demanded by current practice. In my scheme, a country may
be considered predominantly socialist if its standard of living is comparable
to that of the developed inegalitarian nations, if its citizens enjoy
wide-ranging socioeconomic rights and security, and if popular dissatisfaction
with a fairly slow welfare growth is less than it would have been in the face
of greater inequality engendered by significant increases in production and
total material prosperity.
We should not,
however, call a country socialistic if it merely declares the primacy of
socioeconomic rights, but subsists at a low level of quality of life and a low
standard of living, with a sluggish, or even declining rates of growth.
Let us also
note that a commitment to socioeconomic rights might be unrealizable due to the
lack of adequate resources. The Soviet medical system which, though free, now
faces a crisis situation (especially in terms of care for the elderly) is a
good case in point. Because of small budgetary allocations to and excessive
bureaucratization of the medical system (too many doctors are involved in
management, doctors' salaries are low, and it is hard to attract talented
individuals, especially men, into the profession), many people are denied
assistance; the hospitals are instructed not to admit the people over sixty
years of age, and in effect sacrifice the old for the benefit of the working
young and the middle-aged.
Thus, it is essential not to confuse easy
access on the part of the majority of the people to various goods and
services with their guaranteed and free provision. In my view, the
former consideration is socially more important than the latter.
The benefits
of socialism can be provided in a number of different ways - vertically, by the
government, or horizontally, through a compact between private persons and
their organizations such as trade unions.
It should be
pointed out that a very likely consequence of the pursuit of the socialist
ideal is the emergence of a hypertrophied state, for how, without such a state,
is the society to guarantee full employment and extract the 'surplus' from the
enterprising individuals who could refuse to submit voluntarily to excessive
taxation?
Thus, the goal
of creating a society that can simultaneously safeguard the growth of living
standards and that of quality of life
through the (mis?)alliance of socioeconomic and civil rights, could very
well be an impossible dream. There are other, more possible dreams, for
instance, the one of equity that tries to combine individual civil
rights with a minimum of socioeconomic rights.
Different ideals of course do not operate in
isolation from each other - they
interact, but not necessarily converge. It is quite conceivable to
imagine a continuing coexistence of multiple mutually enriching ideals. An
American ideal of individualism and civil rights, for example, has not only
received a boost from racial anti-discrimination laws, greater freedom of
speech, and such legislation as the
Freedom of Information Act, but has also been considerably expanded due to the
influence of socialism by the addition of various socioeconomic rights.
A few more
clarifying remarks are in order concerning the concept of socialism.
Socialists are
of course known to look primarily to socioeconomic rights, as the long-running
ideological battles between the Soviet Union and the civil rights-oriented
Western countries testify. But, paradoxically, it may very well be that
socialists should place a major emphasis on civil rights, because the latter
presuppose the kind of political system that is best at seeking the level of
socioeconomic rights at which the living standards are (minimally) prevented
from falling.
Also, I think
it would be wrong to call a country socialist if its prevailing value system is
militaristic. Even if such a country does well on the score of socioeconomic
rights, it still does not fulfill the promise of welfare growth.
Third, as
Valery Chalidze pointed out to me, socioeconomic rights, such as a right to
work, should not be confused with a corresponding socioeconomic obligation,
which, unfortunately, is the case in the Soviet Union. A Soviet man must work,
otherwise, he may be branded a parasite and punished.
Finally, a few
words about financing socioeconomic rights: this can be done either by
appropriate supplements to recipients' income, or by providing services free of
charge. The choice, I believe, is a function of the general standard of living
in the country, and of its culture. If both are low, the first financing option
is unwise: a man given money to visit a doctor may instead spend it on drink,
because the consumption of liquor has a greater current utility for him than
good health.
Now let us
look at some specific developmental alternatives for the Soviet Union.
Combinatorial Sovietology
Stimulated by
the ideas of the American political scientist , Edward Luttwak, I offer here a
two dimensional matrix linking the primary orientation of Soviet policy -
internal or external - with the leader's evaluation of the country's short-term
(four-five years) and long-term prospects. Each of the four cells in the matrix
carries a value which represents the leader's belief in the possibility of change
(for the sake of simplicity, let this value be either optimistic or
pessimistic) .
Each decision
by the leader is based on his assessment of its overall effect on all four
elements in the matrix. Arguments for and against a pessimistic or optimistic
evaluation in the matrix can be found in
table 1.4.
Each entry in
the matrix depicts a pure strategy. In reality, 'mixed strategies' usually
predominate. It is not too difficult to evaluate the arguments for and against
pure strategies. The weights to be assigned to 'pure' components of mixed
strategies are much harder to calculate. Let us now examine some arguments in
favor of several possible pure strategies.
In one
scenario, the leader evaluates the internal situation pessimistically in the
short run, thinking it the result of a deep systemic crisis that cannot be
quickly remedied; in another scenario,
he also views the long-term internal situation pessimistically, believing that
the system is presently incapable of taking radical steps needed to ensure
progress in the future ; in the third scenario, he views the long-term external
situation pessimistically because the mere existence of three major industrial
democracies, (the US, Japan and West Germany) and China's industrialization
potentially pose all kinds of threats to Russia; in the fourth scenario, he
evaluates the short-term external situation optimistically because his country
has an enormous superiority in conventional weapons and at least a parity in
nuclear ones. The last optimistic evaluation may encourage the new leader to
ally himself the with right-wing chauvinists and seek a solution to the crisis through external expansion, which,
unfortunately, is Russia's traditional method of choice. In the event, say, of
a successful attack on Iran and especially on China, he would be forgiven
anything. Nothing succeeds like success. Victory would make him a hero and
overshadow all else, as it did for Stalin, Peter the Great, and Ivan the Terrible
.
The essay on
Ivan the Terrible in Karamzin's "History of the Russian State" sounds
impressively current. What is Ivan remembered for? For a further centralization
of Russia, for the conquest of Novgorod and Pskov, Kazan and Astrakhan. That
there was an oprichnina (secret police), that he devastated half the
country, that he massacred thousands of human beings, all seems secondary.[11] It is no coincidence that Stalin
extolled Ivan - after Peter the Great, Ivan was his role model. All three
sacrificed their children for the sake of the state, and all three were above
any kind of human feelings.
Successful
expansionism will reunite the people and win prestige. But unlike Stalin,
Khrushchev or Brezhnev, a new Soviet leader will have to execute an aggressive
foreign policy not only for political, but also for economic ends. A conquest
of Western Europe and the Middle East will bring in considerable new resources.
Naturally, the West anticipates such a scenario; the statements of some Western
leaders that, in the event of Soviet aggression, tactical nuclear weapons would
be used, could hold the Soviets back. Furthermore, Israel's convincing military
victory in Lebanon sheds serious doubt on the strength of Soviet conventional
weapons; similarly, the Falklands war and the destruction of the Soviet outpost
in Grenada, show that the West has the will to fight for its ideals.
In another
scenario, a Soviet leader may believe that the U.S.S.R. will, in the future,
flourish economically. The availability of significant numbers of educated and
talented people, and the existence of an industrial base, may support such an evaluation. At the same
time, he may also, for the aforementioned reasons, pessimistically evaluate the
internal situation in the short run. In such an eventuality, an extremely
complex question arises - how to
balance a prospect of a brighter future with a poor situation in the near term.
It will be hard to convince the people to accept a continued low standard of living.
Without material improvements, a major political liberalization will also be
somewhat risky. In this case, it will be very important for a new leader to
obtain economic assistance from the West in a form that neither shackles nor
humiliates him. For the West to help a new Soviet leader overcome the
difficulties of a transitional period will be a rather delicate diplomatic
task. If the Soviet leadership could guarantee that the deep liberalizing
changes in their system are irreversible, the West perhaps could offer the
Soviet Union up to half of what would be saved in reduced arms expenditures to
enable it to get through the transitional period.
In the sixth
scenario, a new leader evaluates the short-term internal future optimistically
by assuming that the military pressure on Russia can be relieved through the
lessening of tensions with China or Western Europe. The resources thus freed
can be used for retooling the old industrial plant and creating new capacities.
By the same token, it is also possible to maintain (and, for stability's sake,
even to somewhat tighten) the existing political and economic structure, while
reminding the people that a centralized economic system successfully managed
the country's industrialization in the 1930s and its reconstruction after World
War II. A new leader, however, may also be pessimistic about the internal
situation in the long-term and the external situation in both the short and
long term. Such a scenario may seem highly attractive to him personally, but
dangerous for the nation if the changes he initiates are not accompanied by the
efforts to create a free society sometime in the distant future. A resolution
of the maturing crisis will only be postponed in this case, with a risk that it
could flare up later with a much greater force. Patching up a system full of
holes, applying Band-Aids to ride out a storm, is not the safest of policies.
I do not
pretend to offer an exhaustive analysis of all possible evaluations a new
leader could make of the existing situation; my goal is rather to draw the
reader's attention to the paradigm that
makes clear the future alternatives open to Russia.
Now let us sum
up what has been said so far. The Soviet Union is in a crisis. A deep illness
infecting the Soviet society is the result of systemic causes: for more than 70
years, the regime has been wantonly wasting its human, natural, and capital
resources. I have noted the alternatives that are available to a new leader - a
choice among them will depend on whether he believes that the Soviet society is
curable. The key question is, does the Soviet Union possess the strength to
overcome its illness, or is the illness pathological? A pathological system is one in which the authorities cannot or
will not, and the people are unable to, remove the barriers to development. In
this case, only a radical intervention from without can cure the disease .
I believe, I
want to believe, that the country has the strength it needs to carry itself out
of the crisis, that is, that the Soviet society is not pathological. Cautious
optimism is to be preferred to incautious pessimism whenever the latter
attitude cannot be conclusively established. The choice is whether to begin the
process of structural change or to try and maintain the system as it is.
Naturally, as always, there is an intermediate possibility - patching the
system. The option, as earlier noted, is a very tricky one, since it could
create false hopes of recovery. Patching could be concealed in a guise of
semi-liberalism and at first look like a recovery. By the same token, half-measures
may produce a mass disillusionment and an even worse spiritual decay.
A central
issue among the various future scenarios generated by the concept of
"Combinatorial Sovietology," will be the leader's evaluation of the
interrelation between expansionism and the country's crisis. Another aspect of
cardinal importance which is present in many of the possible scenarios concerns
the preconditions for future Soviet growth. Movement toward a free society
apparently requires that the country be able in the short term to focus on
solving the long-range problems. Of course, an ideal situation is one in which
the short-term improvements
simultaneously create the preconditions for long - range reforms. However, such
a harmonious policy is hard to execute -
improvements in the short term, if the country is in dire straits,
demand so much energy and mental concentration from the leader, that he has
little time to work on longer range problems. Therefore, in a crisis, external
aid is all the more important to give him a chance to deal more effectively
with the long term. But because it is difficult to verify whether the various
policy initiatives are genuinely reformist, the leader may be tempted to use
external aid just to alleviate the current problems. (Recall the sad experience
of Poland under Gierek.) In other words, a policy of semi-liberalization could
be very ambiguous: it could lead to the creation of preconditions for an
effective reform in the future, or it could merely be a cosmetic means of
postponing the terrible day of the system's unraveling. Therefore, it must be
evaluated with the greatest care.
Now we can
flesh out somewhat the general typology outlined above. The key variables in my
analysis come from a Joseph Berliner's paper on the future of Soviet economy.[12] I broke these variables into ten
categories, adding some to several categories where I deemed appropriate. Under
this classification, and supposing that
only one variable will be utilized in each category, (of course in reality
there can be combinations) it is theoretically possible to count 2,688,000
different scenarios. Naturally, many of
these scenarios are incompatible, (the study of incompatibility can be of
interest in itself) and inevitably only a few of them are truly feasible.
Using the
terms of the scheme, the current situation in the U.S.S.R.. may be
characterized as follows. I. The
erosion of Stalinist ideology. II. A mixture of nationalism and
internationalism. III. A preservation
of the empire through flexible means.
IV. A diminishing role of the Party. V.The erosion of the command model
of economic management and a system of hierarchical appointments. VI.
Decreasing consumption. VII. A significant role of semi-legal and illegal
(corruption, theft) distribution methods. VIII. The development of the country
in the interests of several interest
groups .
To make the
peculiarities of the present period more vivid, let us set it against the
preceding, Stalinist period, and a possible future one. The post-war Stalinist
era was characterized by the following: I. Stalinist ideology. II. Russian
Chauvinism. III. Striving toward world domination. IV. A leading role of the
repressive institutions. V. A very
strong role of the Party in the economy. VI. A strict command system of economic
administration (including the substitution of labor camps for material
incentives) and hierarchical appointments VII. A very slow growth in the
standard of living (especially in the rural regions). VIII. A significant role
of legal unofficial distribution
methods IX. The development of the country in the interests of the party
bureaucracy.
Which scenario
is likely to prevail in Russia over the mid-term? Anticipating somewhat the
conclusions of subsequent chapters, I expect the following. The traditional
Russian ideology is likely to replace the communist one. Communism is playing
an increasingly minor role in the still dominant Stalinist ideology. There are
indications that the Soviet people have not only stopped believing in
communism, they have actually grown hostile to it . Naturally, in the
multinational Soviet empire where the proportion of ethnic Russians is
decreasing, a resurgence of the traditional Russian ideology will encounter
serious problems. The leading role of
the ethnic Russians in the management of the state makes it possible for them,
however, to revive this ideology. I should note that there exists an opinion
that the young generation of Soviet leaders may be more liberal, and may not
follow the traditional Russian ideology. Freedom from marxist dogmatism, a
higher level of education and professional culture, desire for contacts with
the West, and similar arguments are commonly used to support this opinion. If,
however, we recall the general difficulties of introducing a pluralistic
democratic ethos in the U.S.S.R., we can expect that the new leaders too may
opt for the traditional Russian ideology. From history, particularly that of
Germany and Russia, we know that during
crises, a country lacking democratic traditions is likely to return to its
time-tested national ideology.
Erudition and freedom from marxist dogmatism are not insuperable
obstacles to becoming a chauvinist. The joint growth of Russian chauvinism and
nationalism among various social groups (especially among the intelligentsia),
and a deep hostility toward communism, bear out my point. The victory of the
traditional Russian ideology may lead to the revival of Russian chauvinism as a
basis for dealing with the current ethnic unrest. The issue of the empire is a
central one here. The Russian tradition of preserving and expanding the empire
was vigorously continued after the October Revolution. Stalin significantly
extended the land borders of the empire. Khrushchev and the leaders following
him took a new and important step - they began to transform Russia into an
empire with overseas possessions. If Lenin and Stalin ultimately dreamed of
becoming the rulers of the entire
world, the post-Stalinist leaders returned to a more traditional Russian policy
of aspiring only to a world power status. However, there are no guarantees that
the new leaders of the U.S.S.R. will not want
to become global overlords again.
If the
nationalist groups win out, a leading role in economic management will shift to
the state. The Communist party, as an ideological institution, will be replaced
with the Orthodox Church.
A mixed
economy of sorts is likely to emerge. Small-scale production in agriculture, as
well as in consumer goods and services, will devolve to decentralized private
institutions. The major sectors of the economy, where the large-scale
enterprises predominate, will retain their centralized structures of
hierarchical appointments. We may also expect that the use of the theory of
optimal planing will usher in significant changes in management practices. This
theory, together with modern
mathematics and computers, makes it possible to construct a system of
centralized management based on the principle of deconcentration. By
deconcentration I mean that the center will not interfere overmuch in the
internal economic activities of enterprises, and will considerably reduce the
number of parameters by which it plans and judges their activities.
One may assume
that the policy of imperial expansion will be supplemented by increases in the production of consumer goods. In
fact, Soviet leaders of the Brezhnev type had similar goals, but they have not
achieved significant results, as they did not want to change the system. The
new leaders may believe that systemic changes will allow them to pursue
successfully both objectives.
Finally, a word about the social groups that
will likely supervise the process of change.
They are the right-leaning intelligentsia, the military, and the
Komsomol leaders.
Much time may be needed for the Soviet Union
to evolve in the direction of a free society. But it's important to start and,
where possible, to make the positive results irreversible.
Notes and References
1. I believe that
Gorbachev stated this for the first
time in his address titled "O zadachakh partii po korennoi perestroike
upravlenia ekonomikoi," presented at the Central Committee Plenum on 25
June 1987:
"Today, when we
talk about radical restructuring of economic management, it is vital to recall
what the real situation was in our economy back in the late 1970s and early
1980s. By that time the rates of economic growth had fallen so low, as to
virtually signify stagnation." (Pravda, 26 June 1987).
2. Narodnoe
khoziajstvo, 1980:158.
3. It was quite natural
for many establishment conservatives in America, among them Milton Friedman, to
criticize President John F. Kennedy (incidentally, the only Catholic ever to
occupy the White House) for his famous statement "Ask not what your
country can do for you..."
4. This point is borne
out even by anecdotal evidence. Over the past fifteen years, more than 150
thousand Soviet emigres have settled in the United States. Every year they have
to fill out their income tax returns which, as we all know, contain plenty of
loopholes. To use the law in this way to one's advantage smacks to Soviet
emigres of illegality; they can't help thinking that even a perfectly legal
action must directly serve societal purposes. Moreover, for many Soviet
emigres, there is no difference between using the law to one's advantage and
breaking the law.
5. In the thoughts that
follow I borrow heavily from my private conversations with Valery Chalidze, and
from his many publications on the subject of rights. See, for example, V.
Chalidze, The Soviet Human Rights
Movement (New York: The Jacob
Blaustein Institute for the Advancement of Human Rights, 1984).
6. In connection with
this, A.Yanov's The Origins of Autocracy (Berkeley: University of California Press,1981) is of great
interest here. It attempts to show that the preeminently conservative trend in
Russian history, which has endured over the course of many centuries, is the
result of a struggle between contrasting and opposing tendencies rather than of
the country's monolithic nature.
7.The Soviet economic
theory tries to ignore the issue of income from savings. Various attempts to
hide behind the facade of 'earned' savings do not turn the trick because, in
any case, the income in question does not flow from current work effort.
The interest paid on savings deposits in the Soviet Union has almost nothing to
do with the official policy of encouraging savings as against current
consumption. The real reasons lie elsewhere. One is that the authorities want
people to keep their paper money at governmental banking institutions, and not
at home, and thus save themselves the trouble of printing more currency. The
other reason is that in case there is a run on the banks, triggered by a wave
of panic buying or hoarding, the government, using emergency powers, can simply
sequester the holdings. This is precisely what happened at the time of World
War II.
These days, as the
amount of paper money being held by the population accumulates prodigiously,
and the shortages grow worse, there is much talk in the Soviet press about
devising ways to stimulate savings. One of the proposed measures calls for a
sharp increase of the interest rate, which at present equals only two percent.
8. Communism in this
regard is different from socialism in that it not only promises a material
improvement to the people, but also a satisfaction of all their needs.
9. R. Ackoff,
Creating Corporate Future (New York: Wiley, 1981).
10. I call this the
"butterfly effect." When the butterfly comes too close to a lamp,
seeking more light and warmth, it gets singed.
11. My late mother
repeatedly referred to a quote, supposedly by Catherine the Great, to wit:
"What are you talking about people for? - people give birth to more
people, but land doesn't give birth to more land," referring to the idea
that people are expendable.
12. J. Berliner,
"Planning and Management" in A.Bergson and H.Levine,ed. The Soviet
Economy: Toward the Year 2000 (London: George Allen&Unwin,1983),350-90.
2
Multidimensional Approach to the Soviet Political System
General Remarks
The Soviet
political system was created not in accordance with a specific preexisting
blueprint, but rather on the basis of some vague Marxist notions about an ideal
future society, conceptualized as a purposeful, controlled system, or, more
precisely, as a harmonious, planned system. The exigencies of political life
exact a heavy price for such a lack of forethought, giving birth to political systems that are always unpretty,
and oftentimes downright ugly- top-heavy structures pinnacled with an
omnipotent leader. Such was the system that, in basic outline, was built by
Lenin. Stalin only went a little further in the same direction, making the
system even more rigid. The post-Stalinist system has totally retained the basic
structure created by Lenin and embraced by Stalin. The post-Stalinist leaders
though have shown a greater flexibility and have noticeably softened the
regime. If, however, the system itself is not transformed, there can be no
guarantee of Russia's stable peaceful orientation. What is the place of
democratization in the process of the overall systemic transformation?
In disputes
over a future political shape of Russia, democracy is usually offered as an
alternative to autocracy. The democrats clamor for mass participation in
politics; the autocrats insist on having a strong leader when the people are
incapable of making decisions by themselves.
Methodologically,
this level of discussion is absolutely unsatisfactory. Indeed, nothing could be
simpler (or cruder) than to pick one,
supposedly dominant, aspect of a complex structure, imagine that it can have
only a positive or a negative value, and rate all political systems on the
basis of this dichotomous division. A country, then, might be judged democratic
by whether it does or does not respect human rights, or whether it limits or
does not limit its leaders.
It would be a
significant step forward if, instead,
we tried to introduce at least a degree of development along the chosen
dominant dimension, and to delineate certain transitional phases to represent
different kinds of democracies. A mere shift from a binary to a tripartite
approach to human rights, for example, will enable us to speak of fully
democratic countries, that is,. those countries where these rights are
practically respected without exception; semi-democtratic countries, which
observe these rights to a significant degree; and nondemocratic countries,
which do not comply with these rights
at all.
Even this
simple shift, from two to three possible states of the system with respect to
one parameter, can have important policy implications. Consider, for instance,
the conceptual framework of the Carter administration. It started out by
dichotomously dividing all countries into democratic and nondemocratic
according to their human rights performance. The Shah's Iran, which with regard
to that dimension I would rate as semi-democratic, was judged by Carter's
administration to be nondemocratic, as
well as truly subject to American pressure. The results of this policy were not
long in coming.
In truth, however,
no single parameter can do justice to the concept of a free society. Instead,
we have to represent such a society as a multidimensional entity, and
understand that the movement along each axis has to be so regulated as to
ensure an overall positive effect for the system as a whole. Too rapid an
advance along any single dimension, if uncoordinated with the states of
development of the other dimensions, may unhinge the entire system, and throw
it back to a condition even more primitive than the original one (below, I will
illustrate these points with some specific examples, primarily from Russian-Soviet history).
A degree of
the development of a free society is, thus, a function of many independent
variables, complexly interrelated. Unfortunately, when democracy is discussed,
it's usually looked at as a one-dimensional entity, rather than as a
multidimensional one. Therefore, it may be better, when describing a
multidimensional entity, to use the term "free society," and reserve
"democracy" proper to a more narrow sense, as just one of the
dimensions of that society.
The most
important dimension, in my view, is pluralism. It has to do with a special
mechanism of decision making based on a diversity of ideas. Another dimension,
democracy, refers to a number of
competent and responsible individuals participating in this mechanism.
Democracy in this sense should not be confused with ochlocracy, or mobrule.
Other
characteristic dimensions of a free society are the separation of powers in the
system (ideological, legislative, executive, and judicial), and the openness of
the system (free import and export of information, goods, and people). Only
when all these dimensions are fully developed can we speak of real restraints
upon the power of the leader; and these restraints are a necessary condition
for any long-term progress.
Each dimension
is an aggregate that can be further decomposed into subdimensions corresponding
to different aspects of the relevant aggregate dimension. I will give some
examples of these subdimensions, particularly with reference to pluralism. For
the sake of simplicity, I shall use the term 'dimension' disregarding its
degree of aggregation. In principle, each dimension ranges over a continuum.
But it could be split up into stages or phases, each with its own
distinguishing characteristics.
Thus, a free
society represents a multidimensional field, with each dimension having a
certain number of stages. I have to repeat that the development of a country
has to proceed in a rather sophisticated manner along each of these axes, so
that the stages across all axes be always in harmony with one another. The effectiveness of a social organization is
determined by its ability to form multidimensional systems incorporating many
stages along each dimension, and subsequently integrate the processes that take
place in the system.
Ideology and Ideocracy in the U.S.S.R.
The Soviet
Union was created as an ideological system designed to realize the great goal
of building communism. The promises to build communism in a short time, that
is, within the life span of a single generation, were given by Lenin, in his
famous speech at the 1920 Komsomol Congress, and by Khruchshev, in the 1961
Program of the CPSU. Stalin, too, made similar pledges, but more cautiously.
Addressing the Eighteenth Party Congress in 1939, Stalin said:
"We have
outstripped the major capitalist countries technologically and in terms of
industrial growth. This is very good. But it's not enough. We also have to bypass
them economically. We can and must do that. Only if we overtake the major
capitalist countries economically, can we hope to completely meet our demand
for consumer goods, and take a leap from the first stage of Communism to its
second stage.
But this takes
time, and lots of it. We can't overtake
the major capitalist countries economically in two or three years. This will
take a little longer."[13]
Only in the
post-Khrushchevian period have the Soviet leaders actually stopped making any
specific promises about the timetable for building communism, but the goal
itself remains an important part of the official ideology. To be sure, the
attitude of both the leadership and the people toward that part of the
ideological corpus has changed considerably. In these days of glasnost, there
are many shades of opinion on this score, ranging from sincere professions of
faith in Communism to its open criticism in the media.
There is one
intermediate position between these extremes that, I think, is crucial for
understanding the present situation in the country. This position came into its
own during the life of Stalin, and since then has remained largely intact. Let
us, therefore, call it the "Stalinist Cocktail."
Stalinism, as
an ideology, represents a combination of Marxism-Leninism and the old
traditional Great Russian ideology
(belief in the tsar, the fatherland and Orthodoxy). There is a fairly
wide-spread conviction that Stalin created this ideology only after the war's
turning point, or even after the war's end. There was, for example, Stalin's
famous Kremlin address to the Red Army
Commanders on May 24, 1945, in which he raised a toast to the Great
Russian people "who are the most outstanding nation among the ethnic groups
that make up the Soviet Union."[14]
The Kremlin
speech notwithstanding, I think that the above conviction is in error. Stalin
started to promote the Russian idea as early as 1924 when he, using
anti-Semitism among other means, managed to isolate the party's left wing, that
is, the proponents of permanent revolution. However, in the 1920s the ''Russian
idea'' was still hidden. It came to the
surface at the beginning of the 1930s and blossomed in later years (for more
details, see the part 3, "
Nationalism.")
Relatives of
Alexander Kosarev (a Komsomol leader who perished during the Yezhovshchina)
told me that after a meeting with Stalin, (the event occurred in 1934?) Kosarev
recounted how Stalin openly insisted that his (Stalin's) person be glorified -
of course, not for his own personal gain, but for the sake of socialism. In other words, we see that the first part
of the triptych of Russian ideology, the image of the tsar, was being born
again.
Another thing
that occurred in this period was the rebirth of faith in the fatherland - the second part of the Russian ideological
triptych. This is something that is widely known and scarcely requires special
examples.
The third part
was religion. I know from several prominent historians of the existence of
documents, dating to the mid 1930s, concerning a policy change with respect to
priests. Subsequently, the Bezbozhnik
(Atheist) society and the magazine of the same name were closed down. Signs of
this turnaround became more visible after the beginning of World War II, when,
in 1942, Stalin received the patriarch and gave him his permission to open
seminaries, even though the antireligious Marxist propaganda continued as
before.
Dating the
revival of the "Russian idea" by the early 1930s, may help us to
explain why there was a certain discrimination in the annihilation of various
groups during the Great Purges. Why did such writers as Boris Pasternak, Andrej
Platonov, Mikhail Bulgakov, Anna Akhmatova, and Mikhail Zoshchenko survive?
They all died of natural causes. My theory is that in the heyday of communist ideology, the leader feared
'heretics' rather than 'atheists.' These writers were atheists in terms of
communism, inasmuch as they rejected the Soviet ideology in total. Furthermore,
they were Russian artists, a not insignificant circumstance, and therefore
could be trusted. The leadership understood that these people did not like the
Soviet regime, but were not about to do anything bad. Far more dangerous were
the heretics, such people as Isaak Babel, because he somewhat believed in the
Communist dream but disagreed with the leadership on how they were going about
pursuing it. Worse, he wanted to uncover the root causes and find out where
things had gone wrong. And Babel wasn't an ethnic Russian. Incidentally, the
opposite situation seems to be the case today when the ideological structure is
faltering - the atheists are more feared than the heretics. That's why the
authorities will be infinitely patient with the likes of Roy Medvedev while suppressing outspoken
anti-Soviet dissenters, left-wing and right-wing alike.
In this way,
Stalin created an ideology - a kind of 'fulminating powder'- in which such
slogans as " The Workers of the
World Unite!" "The Workers
Have No Homeland," and "Religion is the Opiate of the Masses"
virtually coexisted with "For the Faith, the Tsar, and the
Fatherland."
It would seem
that the Stalinist ideology was internally inconsistent: the three parts of the
traditional Great Russian ideological triptych completely contradicted Marxism.
It is well known that Marxism does not approve of personality cults,
nationalism, and religion. How were the two mutually exclusive ideologies reconciled? Was this not Orwell's
'doublethink?'
Yes, it was
doublethink, a phenomenon otherwise known as 'split consciousness.' Common
sense people infected with doublethink can hold two or more contradictory
assertions at the same time. If this kind of defective common sense is not
challenged, it can examine each proposition
in isolation from the rest - a sort of ideological 'divide and conquer'
perpetrated by the mind.
Let me
illustrate this point with an example. In the Soviet Union, the following model
of Lenin exists: Lenin was the paragon of modesty; during the Civil War, he
refused to accept special food packages, gave away his meager rations to
starving children; he was humble in both life-style and dress. At the same
time, the Soviet government opens a Lenin museum in Gorki, near Moscow, on the
grounds of the former country estate of a Tsarist high official. There, among
other things, we are told that Lenin came to Gorki to hunt. How could the
paragon of modesty have a country estate where he came for hunting with
well-fed hounds? What kind of an impression could this make on 'commoners?'
What kind of a hero goes off hunting and stays in a luxurious palace lodge when
the country is starving ? But Soviet
people readily accept both versions of Lenin as true.
The same
phenomenon of doublethink existed on a larger scale: the two mutually
exclusive sides of Stalinism, Marxism and Russian nationalism, were 'bought' by the masses. The official Soviet ideology even today
differs little from this Stalinist
Cocktail.
Glasnost,
however, has already spawned a new modification in the official ideological
corpus, a democratic one. Such publications as Ogonyek and Moscovskie
Novosti run stories that assert democracy as a positive liberal ideal for
the country. I am talking about the
positive goals, and not merely a criticism of the official ideology, especially
its communist element, because the sharpest critics of communism belong not to
the liberal camp, but to the nationalist circles. The magazine Novyj Mir,
which leans toward moderate nationalism, is a good case in point.
Therefore, I
believe it is incorrect to assert that the Soviet ideology is completely
Marxist. Moreover, as the ideology
evolved , its communist element was increasingly pushed aside. To sharpen the
point, let us distinguish between the goal and the means of the communist
ideology. By the goal I mean the
construction of communism. The Communist slogans have by now turned into the
objects of derision. Khrushchev, with his promises to build communism in twenty
years, finally managed to kill the communist ideal in the Soviet Union. The
shortest Soviet political joke consists of one word, and that word is
"Communism." In a popular Soviet film, Little Vera, released
in 1988, the heroine openly snickers at communism as a societal goal.[15] This part of the communist ideology is
dead as a doornail.
By the means of Communist ideology I mean economic
planning and organization. This tenet of communism does accord with the Russian
mentality, and many still believe in it. Therefore, when I speak of the
'bankruptcy of communist ideology' I mean that its ideals are laughed at. Many people, however, still labor under the
illusion that the existing system is sound, and can even be significantly
improved.
Does this mean
that the communist part of the Soviet ideology as a whole can be completely
ignored? I don't think so, because the leaders continue to manipulate the
symbols of the communist faith, albeit mainly for outside consumption: a
"scientific" promise of building heaven on earth which Marxism holds
out, is ineradicable, and will always attract devout followers. The Soviet
leaders though may just as well
manipulate the anti-communist symbols, if the interests of the state so
dictate. I recall a conversation I had
with an old communist at the end of the 1950s, when Khrushchev invited Nasser
to Moscow. My friend's outrage knew no bounds: how could they receive such a
person in Moscow, place him as a honorary guest on top of Lenin' s tomb, and
award him the gold star of a Hero of the Soviet Union after he had annihilated
the Communist party in his own country? But Khrushchev well understood that, besides
ideology, there were his personal
interests, state interests, and imperial interests - and these were the main things.
How did Hitler
resolve the ideological problems after concluding the nonaggression pact with
Stalin in 1939? A reconciliation of fascism with communism was bound to look
impossible in the eyes of the German people, especially after many years of
anticommunist propaganda. One of Hitler's underlings - I think it was Rosenberg
- proposed to reformulate the essence of Soviet communism as 'the Slavic
version of fascism.' This semantic device helped to justify an ideological
alliance with the Soviet Union: the Russians did not have communism, but rather
'the Slavic version of fascism.'
In other
words, when a politician needs to dress up his actions in some specific
ideological garb, he can do it quite
subtly, as the example of Hitler demonstrates. Therefore, one should not take
at face value the communist rhetoric of
Soviet leaders.
Now let us
come back to the evolution of Stalinism.
As the role of
communism in the Stalinist ideology decreased, its other part, the
"Russian idea," gathered momentum and grew to such an extent that it
threatened to become the wave of the
future. Why is the so-called Russian wing so dangerous? Because it has a long
tradition behind it, a tradition only temporarily interrupted by the Bolshevik
Revolution, and revived quickly under the Stalinist Thermidor. Therefore,
studying the evolution of Stalinism helps us to better predict and understand
the future course of Soviet developments.
Is nationalism
really so dangerous? The experience of many countries in the second half of the
twentieth century is marked by a resurgence of nationalism. I believe in ethnic
variety, and know of no better means to preserve it than through the system of
nation-states. Nationalist sentiments are not bad in and of themselves,
provided they do not turn into chauvinism (incidentally, regressing a bit,
recall that if at the beginning Stalin championed Russian nationalism, at the
end he became a hard-core Russian chauvinist). The danger of nationalism is
that it can grow and change into chauvinism. This is especially true of a large
country with a global war-making capability. If such a country in addition
finds itself in a crisis, the danger is magnified manifold. Under such
conditions, fanatical nationalists and zealots with an abundant emotional charge needed to run the country,
could come to power. They would be ready to go to great lengths and to make
heavy sacrifices to 'save' the country and satisfy their own interests.
Fanatics never doubt the sincerity of their cause. That's what's terrifying.
Their chauvinism, just like any other kind of fanaticism, could cause much
grief.
But no matter
how strong the nationalist ideology is in the Soviet Union, and whatever its
attractions for the Russian people, one cannot ignore the possibility that some
kind of a liberal ideology may develop there. The country does have a
significant liberal intelligentsia which continues the great traditions of
Russian liberalism. There is also an alternative of maintaining
essentially the present ideology, while
reducing in it the role of nationalism.
This could be done by replacing the currently Moscow-oriented but indigenously
recruited leaders in the Republics with Moscow-bred cadres, who will smash up
the separatist elements.
Ideocracy.
The system
that the Bolsheviks set up in Russia came to be run by the organization that,
in theory, was to be responsible only for the ideological questions. But, as
has already been intimated in the previous section, this organization, the
Communist Party of the Soviet Union, controls all aspects of societal life,
both in space and in time. And this role of the Party is codified in the
country's Constitution.
The Bolsheviks
were by no means the first people to create an ideocratic system. In the past,
these systems have primarily been theocracies headed by religious leaders with
unlimited power. For example, almost 150 years, until the middle of the
eighteenth century, the Jesuits virtually ran a state within the state in
Paraguay. Theirs, however, was a simple control system, because the Jesuits
ruled only over the Indians, who themselves did not belong to their order. The
Indians were organized around agricultural communes presided over by two
Jesuits wielding total authority. Their decisions concerning the internal life
of the commune were carried out by the Indians[16].
By contrast,
the Soviet ideocratic system is one of the most complex systems of its kind.
The ruling ideocratic party in the U.S.S.R.
controls all aspects of societal life both in space and in time. Party leaders
have to resolve all issues: Should ballerina Maya Plisetsky be allowed to
travel abroad?[17] In what direction should the economy
develop? What should be the attitude toward religion? What foreign policy
decisions to make? How to guide the activities of the communist parties in the
West? Inevitably, they also have to take care of the intra-party activities
that concern several million party members. ''Secular" institutions,
essentially combining legislative and judicial powers, were set up to promptly
implement those decisions that went beyond intra-party issues. These secular
institutions, however, were largely staffed by members of the selfsame party.
The party
apparatus is organized along geographical lines, and vested with total
authority over all organizations within a given territorial unit. Secular
institutions are both functional and territorial in nature, with the functional
hierarchy being the predominant one: territorially, secular bodies can control
only local organizations. However, In a basic
unit of control, be it an office or a factory, the situation is the
exact opposite of what it is at the top of the pyramid, with the secular leadership
enjoying undivided authority.
To manage the
system, Soviet leadership thus needs to coordinate the activities of three
separate hierarchies: the party
apparatus, the secular functional bodies, and the secular territorial bodies.
Conflicts of interest between these three sets of actors engender enormous
friction and inefficiencies.
Below, I"ll try to show that the Soviet
system can hardly be improved without eliminating this triple hierarchy,
separating the Party as an ideological body from the State, and drastically
modifying secular institutions. It goes without saying that the transformation
of the Soviet Union into a free society conceived as a multidimensional entity,
will require considerable time and plenty of meticulous work.
An important
methodological guideline for such an undertaking was rather successfully
formulated by an outstanding Russian literary critic, Mikhail M. Bakhtin.
Writing about the poetics of Dostoevsky, he said:
"Thus,
no new artistic genre ever nullifies or replaces old ones. But at the same time
each fundamentally and significantly new genre, once it arrives, exerts influence on the entire circle of old
genres: the new genre makes the old ones, so to speak, more conscious; it forces
them to better perceive their own possibilities and boundaries, that is, to
overcome their own naivete. Such, for example, was the influence of the
novel as a new genre on all the old literary genres: on the novella, the
narrative poem, the drama, the lyric. Moreover, a new genre can have a positive
influence on old genres, to the extent, of course, that their generic natures
permit it; thus, for example, one can speak of a certain
"novelization" of old genres in the epoch of the novel's flowering.
The effect of new genres on old ones in most cases promotes their renewal and
enrichment."[18]
In my political philosophy I adhere to the
principle that if an institution appears on the scene and endures for a long time, it must be fulfilling an important
integrative function. Therefore, the proposals to dismantle such institutions should not be taken lightly. Moreover, if some institutions have suffered
an untimely denigration, or even destruction, we should think of ways to
rebuild them.
Pragmatic
arguments about the benefits of eliminating a particular institution may prove
to be narrow-minded, and fail to take into account the institution's various
influences on society's integration. I do not dispute the existence of
dysfunctional institutions, primarily those that try to fulfill too many functions
at the same time. Such institutions
tend to completely dominate the
governmental bodies - an ideocracy is an appropriate example. Still, I
do think it entirely reasonable to simply
destroy them. A more appropriate
course would be to concentrate on
gradually limiting their power through the introduction of new institutions.
I believe that
the radicals, who try to dismantle entrenched political institutions rather
than to elucidate exactly what functions they perform and attempt to limit
their role, are mistaken.
Thoughts on the Use of Monarchies and Aristocracies
The comments
at the end of the last section are particularly applicable to the following two
institutions: aristocracy and monarchy.
On the
Use of Monarchies.
Seemingly
outdated, monarchy can still perform a number of very important social
functions. It derives its meaning from representing the nation's enduring
values. When the monarch is constitutionally limited and excluded from direct
participation in politics, he becomes a symbol of his country's age-old
traditions, its history, its character;
in other words, everything of which the people are proud. A king's visit abroad is a particularly
significant demonstration of these principles, and not, as a rule, a
politically-motivated decision.
Although it's not quite de rigueur, academically, to borrow thoughts from the
reactionaries-good liberals never quote Hitler approvingly - I cannot resist
the temptation to cite an opinion on the importance of monarchy expressed by
the famous Soviet mathematician and a Russian nationalist, Igor Shafarevich. In
one of our private conversations, he said that the society should have two
opposing kinds of institutions - one,
to be praised, the other, to be criticized.
It is not exactly clear whether it's beneficial to make the same
institution an object of love and of criticism. The British monarches, the
symbols of national unification and integration, rarely if at all draw critical
fire.
If
you must criticize, there's the Parliament -- go ahead and criticize the
government. But there is also something
constant, revered, like the Ten Commandments.
The laws can be modified as needed, but something should remain sacred.
The
people's genuine love of the monarchy is very apparent in Holland. The king's birthday is a national
holiday. The people, dressed in holiday
attire, come out into the streets, enjoy themselves, and express pride in their
country.
In
many places, the love of the people for a monarch ( a constitutionally limited
one) also reflects pragmatic considerations. When visiting Thailand in 1983, I
attempted to make contact with "the masses." For a tourist unacquainted with the local
language, such contacts often boil down to conversing with taxi drivers or the
hotel staff, as they know a little bit of English. I asked two cab drivers the same question: "How do you feel
about your King? Why do you need him?
It seems a waste of money to pay a person who actually has no power!" One of the drivers - both of them, by the
way, turned out to be 'monarchists' - gave a particularly curious reply: it was precisely because the king was
uninvolved in politics that he was able to be honest. Parliamentarians and
civil servants, immersed in the current affairs of state, were corrupt. The
king, according to him, was also able to pay more attention to common people.
In
addition to its symbolic influence, a monarchy performs a number of important social functions. For example, a
British king or queen, being a symbol of the nation, can virtually rehabilitate
a formerly stigmatized official by inviting him to a formal reception. This is
what I believed happened with Profumo.
The
destruction of monarchy in a country where it has existed for a long time is
extremely dangerous. It may very quickly be replaced by a different
institution, which will perform essentially the same role, but much less
benignly. While an established monarchy may have accumulated a vital experience
of prudent governance, institutions that replace it often fall into the hands of
political novices, who, in their eagerness for abrupt and decisive action, can
do much damage to the country.
Let's
look at Iran. What was the cardinal mistake of the Islamic Revolution? In my view, it was the destruction of
monarchy. Maybe the shah was
bad, maybe the dynasty was bad, but it was not right to destroy the
institution. As soon as it was
destroyed, the resulting vacuum was filled by Khomeini. And in comparison with Khomeini who behaved
like a caliph, the shah was an archliberal.
The
need to maintain the institution of limited monarchy has been recognized by a
number of historical figures, for example, by General Douglas MacArthur, who
preserved the institution of the emperor in Japan, and by General Francisco
Franco, who transferred power to King
Carlos of Spain.
Right
after the Revolution, Pavel N. Miliukov declared that the tragedy of Russia was
the elimination of the tsar: not the tsar himself, not the dynasty, but
specifically the institution. In a
country where the personality of the monarch played such a significant role
over the course of centuries, this was risky.
The Bolsheviks understood the significance of the moment. Nicholas II was replaced by Lenin who
exploited the image of "the people's tsar." The famous painting Lenin
with the Messengers is the most obvious testimony to this.
In the U.S.S.R., Stalin and other leaders
have occasionally been taken for tsars. Once, at a taxi stand in Moscow, an
elderly woman came up to me and asked how to get to the Novodevichy Monastery. "I want to pay my respects to Tsar
Nikita," she said. "And
then," she continued, "I'm going to the Red Square to pay my respects
to Tsar Vladimir." I know of a
similar story in the Kirov region where, during the war, a woman called Stalin
"Tsar Joseph."
Thus,
strange as it may seem, I would like to see a restoration of constitutional
monarchy in Russia. One should not, however, confuse a constitutional monarchy
with a "monarchical constitution." Under the former arrangement, the
institution of monarchy is only one of a number of institutions forming the
pluralistic political structure, the other being represented by an elected
parliament which fills top slots in the executive branch, an independent judiciary, opposition
parties, a free press, and the like. Under a "monarchical
constitution," the monarch, with the help of his own constitution, more or less creates an illusion of
a structurally sophisticated political system.
In fact, he alone rules the country, making decisions on major issues,
chiefly those of war and peace. Of course, after seventy years of
Communism, resurrecting the institution
of monarchy in Russia may seem bizarre or even impossible. However, if we consider the rapid gains of
the Russian right wing movement and those groups within it that call for the
restoration of absolute monarchy, the only thing that will appear bizarre in my
proposal is the insistence on constitutional monarchy.
On the
Use of Aristocracy.
The
modern civilized world universally espouses a negative view of the institution
of aristocracy. Of the developed nations, only Great Britain has preserved a
system of aristocratic titles. Criticism of aristocracy, of hereditary
aristocrats in particular, is founded on the rejection of the idea of an
exclusive ruling elite.
First,
a few theoretical observations. There is a well-known distinction in economics
between public and private goods. Public goods (e.g., national defense, lawmaking) are those goods the amount of
which does not diminish with consumption. The amount of private goods (e.g.,
food, clothing) does diminish with consumption. The production of public goods
is the responsibility of the government since they are not marketable products.
Private goods can be produced either by the government or by the market.
Looking at history, we can see that the
nations with a strong commitment to the production of public goods, had a
pretty powerful aristocracy. The existence of aristocracy proved a tremendous
long-term boon to them. Why?
If
the government is involved in the production of goods, it pari passu is involved in
the appointment of people who have to supervise the process of production. As
far as appointments are concerned, the loyalty of an employee to his employer
is the decisive factor. The professional qualifications of a would-be employee
may also seem important, nay controlling, for an employer chiefly preoccupied
with national welfare. Actually, the
employer's interest in his own power is usually so much stronger than his civic
concerns that he easily overlooks the employee's professional defects and
concentrates on his fealty instead. This practice, if unchecked, eventually
threatens to weaken the national leadership. The performance of dedicated
employees suffers because of the fear to voice their opinions; considerations
of efficiency give way to considerations of personal safety and the avoidance
of any behavior that may provoke the accusation of disloyalty from the
employer. If the employee has climbed fairly high in the hierarchy, and has tasted the fruits of prestige and
material well-being, the mere thought of forced retirement and loss of benefits
is enough to keep him in line.
It
was largely the institution of aristocracy that ameliorated the employee's fear
of losing his job. Being a member of
the aristocracy pretty much allowed one to preserve one's social and material
status regardless of one's position. Of course, this guarantee worked only in a
nontyrannical regime; under tyranny, no
institution could save a disloyal person.
I
believe that one of the reasons why the institution of aristocracy has survived
almost intact in Great Britain even after the bourgeois revolution had to do
with the fact that Britain was an imperial country, mainly interested in the
production of public goods. The military and civil service played a vital role
throughout the British Empire, in London and colonies alike. The role of the
businessman as the producer of private goods was much less important. Although
forty years have passed since the collapse of the British Empire, traditional
values, as championed by the producers of public goods, have maintained their
strength in many ways, and that in spite of the importance of enterprising
individuals in modern economic development. The nationalization of British industry
was also symptomatic of this condition, recalling in many ways the earlier
emphasis on the production of public goods. To the present day, the societal
role of the businessman is not highly valued by British establishment, although an entrepreneur may indeed get
titled for his economic contributions.
These conclusions, truth be told, are based
on anecdotal evidence rather than on serious sociological research. An English
friend of mine who shares my views on the role of the businessman in contemporary
British society, told me how at a prestigious Welsh annual music festival he
observed the well-bred English aristocrats looking disdainfully at those
businessmen who arrived in expensive luxury cars (and even helicopters).
In a sharp contrast to England, the United
States is a country that has never known an aristocracy. Again, the distinction
between private and public goods may furnish part of the explanation. From its
very inception the United States stressed
the production of private goods. The nation's founders conceived it as a
country of independent farmers; it has since become a country in which
entrepreneurs, unhindered by governmental bureaucracy, can utilize their
talents in the production of private goods. The decentralization of the country,
and its avoidance of foreign entanglements, meant that for quite some time the
production of public goods was only a small proportion of the national income.
Suffice it to note that at the turn of the century, the United States'
expenditures on defense were smaller than the total revenue from excise taxes.
Although
American economic achievements are considerable, the same cannot be said of the
production of public goods. The US political system has yielded largely
mediocre leaders over the past three decades. The war in Vietnam and the
unsuccessful attempt to free the hostages in Iran, demonstrate that the quality
of military leadership also leaves a lot to be desired.
Possibly, the lack of political and military
leaders of a number and caliber required by the complexity of modern life and
the new global role of the United States, is partly due to an exceedingly high
importance that the American value system has long attached to producers of
private goods.
What
has been said of the imperative to preserve the employees's independence in the
sphere of government-produced public goods, holds equally true for those
instances when the government is involved in the production of private goods.
When the production of both public and
private goods is significant, as is now the case in the majority of developed
countries, it is very difficult to maintain a balance in social values and
institutions needed to foster a harmonious development.
The
institution of the aristocracy had existed in Russia for centuries, and it had
struggled long and hard to enhance its autonomy: even as late as the eighteenth
century, Russian aristocrats were still subject to corporal punishment. One can
easily find fault with Russian aristocracy, especially with those of its members
who were close to the last tsar. But on the whole, the Russian nobility could
be justly proud of having produced many honorable individuals. After the
Bolshevik Revolution, the institution of the aristocracy was immediately
abolished. Most noblemen managed to leave the country; many others were killed.
Only a small part of the aristocracy miraculously survived.
Nowadays,
there is a wide-spread opinion in the U.S.S.R. that aristocracy may be
beneficial[19]. For our purposes, it will be
sufficient to point out the marked attitudinal changes toward the old Russian
aristocracy. In the 1920s and 1930s, people tried to hide their aristocratic
roots, fearing all sorts of educational and career complications. In the 1960s
and 1970s, the descendants of aristocrats proudly confessed their ancestry to
strangers and friends alike, believing that this would enhance their social
position.
Although
there is no system of real aristocratic titles in the U.S.S.R., the scholarly
ranks of "Academic" or "Correspondent Member" of the
Academy of Sciences resemble them in some essential respects. These academic
ranks are prestigious, and confer on their bearers not only considerable social
status but material benefits as well, which benefits, by Soviet standards, are
rather significant. The case of Andrej
Sakharov, who though exiled to Gorky, was allowed to keep his title of Academic
with all its privileges, confirms just how important this title is.
The role of Soviet government in the
production of public and private goods will most likely remain an essential one
in the observable future. Therefore, I believe that the idea of reviving the
institution of aristocracy merits serious attention. It stands to reason that
aristocratic titles should not necessarily be hereditary (as is now the case in
Great Britain), and that other measures to reduce the negative aspects of the
institution may be introduced.
Pluralism and Democracy
I want to stress my belief in pluralism as a
key factor in the life of social systems. This is because, on the one hand, the
society develops in a situation characterized by a fairly high degree of
indeterminism, when even the probabilities of success of various alternatives
are unknown, and, on the other, because the members of the society exhibit a
wide divergence in their value systems. Given these two conditions, the most
dangerous people, to paraphrase a Soviet poet, Alexander Galich, are those
" who know the way it must be."
A developed
pluralistic mechanism is characterized by (1) availability of different
developmental programs; ( 2) selection of one program for a foreseeable future;
(3) monitoring the implementation of the program; (4) changing the
program if new conditions arise or the program is found to be
ineffective in the course of its implementation. The choice as to the actual
number of people directly participating in pluralistic decision - making
should, it seems, be of secondary importance.
The
development of a pluralistic mechanism could start with individuals receiving
real rights to criticize the programs professionally prepared by the leadership. The next step is the
establishment of legal opposition. The opposition initially should not be
charged with the task of elaborating a development strategy as sophisticated as
the one being offered by the leadership. What's important in the emergence of
organized legal opposition is that the previously atomized criticisms now have
a single voice. Pluralism reaches full maturity when there appears an
opportunity to elaborate and present a manifold of national development
programs, together with suggestions for their implementation. I speak of a
manifold here because at this stage we do not yet try and rate the programs.
The content of the program is of no importance; what matters is that it exists,
and is different. The need for a manifold of unrated programs is dictated by many reasons. One reason, alluded to
above, stems from an essential indeterminism of social life. Since the initial
cost of developing a manifold of programs is relatively small, free countries
have practically unlimited opportunities to engage in that activity.
For new and
original programs to emerge, it is necessary to have independent
organizations. They have to be
institutionalized, and have access to information to be able to offer
contrasting and realistic programs; otherwise, they become impotent and can be
easily beaten. If only one political party exists, factions within it cannot
long survive. It seems that the tolerance for factions is possible only in a
multiparty system, in which party leaders fear the potential loss of supporters
to the opposition. (Didn't a rise of different branches of Christianity
precipitate the appearance of different orders in the Catholic church?)
In turn, a
multiparty system requires a variety of independent sources of financing party activities. Any organization sets its
own priorities, and a single source of financing can choke off many new programs[20].
Program development is a multistage process.
It begins with the creation of new ideas and ends with a detailed blueprint for action. A manifold, of which I spoke earlier,
relates precisely to the initial innovation-producing stages of program
development. It is here that unlimited pluralism, with independent sources of
financing, is vital. The subsequent development of these ideas may require
considerable resources to set up independent organizations and, ultimately,
political parties. The job of the parties is to transform these ideas into
practical strategies and policies.
Though manifolds
are essential for long-term progress, at any given point in time only one
program predominates-a system simply cannot function according to several
programs simultaneously. Prioritizing
the programs means that only one of them (or only one combination) is selected, the one needed for the
current operation of the system. I am not going to discuss the well known problems of political philosophy
that deal with the principles of selecting a program from a manifold (different
voting schemes), monitoring the program implementation, and establishing an
appropriate mechanism for changing programs.
Thus,
pluralism is above all a question of the development of various points
of view and a free choice among them. What do I mean by freedom here? All too
often freedom is reduced to choosing
in the present from a menu of options accumulated in the past. This won't do,
for freedom also demands that diversity be created today, out of which one can
choose tomorrow. Freedom, therefore, requires two conditions: the existence of
a diversity of competing points of view in the present and the provision for
maintaining a diversity of views for tomorrow.
Lenin' s
principle of democratic centralism dealt only with the first condition: there
exists a diversity of opinions, let's choose; the choice having been made,
everyone must fall into line. The majority's one-time choice supersedes the
interests of the minority, that is, of the very people who today are developing
the new ideas, from which we want to be able to choose tomorrow. The creative
minority was crushed in the Soviet Union.
I recall a
true story told by a friend of mine from the city of Poltava. On one hot summer
day, thousands of Poltavians rushed to a nearby river to escape the scorching
heat. The trolleys were filled to overflowing. The driver of a trolly asked the
passengers at the first stop, "ls the majority going to the beach?"
Hearing an agreeable chorus of "da's" in response, he said,
"Then we'll travel non-stop." The voices of the minority not headed
for the beach were drowned out by the cries of the majority. The image of 'democracy the Poltava style'
has stayed with me as a symbol of the principle of democratic centralism.
The Soviet
system has nearly always tried to suppress diversity and pluralism, without
consideration of means, and nip in the bud any competing views that could
challenge the prevailing dogmas of various powers that be.
Pluralism is
not just the presence of many viewpoints, it is also their interaction.
Therefore, pluralism presupposes a mechanism for replacing one viewpoint with
another: the supporters of one position, pursuing their own interests, closely
follow the actions of the supporters of competing positions. When one program
is selected, the others observe how it evolves; if it's discovered to be
leading the country astray, there are other alternative programs on hand to
correct or replace it with. That's pluralism as a dynamically operating system.
Comparing a
pluralistic mechanism with other possible mechanisms of decision making,
reveals a decisive role of the intellectual manifold. The principle of
democratic centralism proposed by the Russian Bolsheviks led by Lenin at first
looks very similar to a pluralistic mechanism. According to the principal of
democratic centralism, decision making
has to be based on a manifold. Its transformation into a singular diversity,
that is, some particular policy, is carried out in keeping with the majority
rule. After the choice is made, everyone must abide by it. But no mention is
made of how to ensure these same conditions for subsequent choices, when it becomes necessary to replace the
existing program. One can only assume that the manifold for the next choice
situation will be created by accident. If we recall that a communist ideology
(just like any other monistic worldview) means the acceptance of a single
truth, it becomes very easy to destroy various parties and factions within the
main party. The manifold degenerates or, at best, is reduced to mere
differences of opinion of the members of the ruling oligarchy. The country's
capacity for long-term prosperity is thus gravely impaired, if not altogether
lost.
What is the
relationship between pluralism and democracy? I believe that it depends on the
level at which the populace is allowed to take part in decision making (local,
state, or federal). Here, when I speak
of democracy, I mean popular participation in decision making at the highest
level, that is, in deciding upon the
issues affecting the development of the entire country. My observations on
democracy are less relevant to the lower levels of social hierarchy.
Democracy aims
at involving as many people as possible, ideally everyone, in the process of
decision making at all levels, and at the highest level especially. But such
factors as personal competency, responsibility, and commitment to pluralism are
also crucial for democracy. I speak
here of competency in a broad sense that involves not just the educated elite,
but the grass roots as well. Recall the difference between democracy and
ochlocracy, i.e. power of the mob. Perhaps the weakness and even the downfall
of many free societies was the result of their inability to put an end to the
process of ochlocratization (that is, a gradual involvement of more and more
incompetent and irresponsible people in pluralistic decision making) and return
to democracy.
There are
certain cultural conditions that have to be met before democracy can come into
being. One of these conditions - a necessary, but not a sufficient one - is the
philosophy of individualism (not to be confused with egotism, with everyone
pursuing their own interests while ignoring the interests of others).
What I have in
mind is the Western conception of the individual: I am able to be an individual only if I recognize others as
individuals. I'm unique and you're unique, and both of us have equal rights
which must be mutually respected. Russia does not partake of this tradition.
Not coincidentally, the concept of privacy does not exist among the Russians,
and their language has no word for it.
But in Russia,
in the lore of the Russian village, there is, as Professor Szymon Chodak justly
notes, something else: the image of the truth-seeker (pravdoliubets). In
the Russian tradition, it is not pluralism and tolerance that are stressed, but
rather the Truth, a single, absolute and universal Truth that exists somewhere
and must be found. The cultural roots are different in Russia - they are the
roots nourished by the striving for unity.
Soviet emigres
in the West exhibit the same intolerance and lack of understanding of the need
for diversity, for many truths. I have observed these true believers. They are
so sincere, so absolutely sure that what they wish for themselves is also good
for others, that they accuse their opponents of being the servants of the
Satan, that is, the KGB. These people are not in the least cynical, and that's
just what's so scary - they can't even comprehend their limitations .
It seems
dangerous to give people so steeped in the 'truth-seeking' tradition the right
to elect and be elected. They could easily produce a totalitarian regime
because they are predisposed to turn to someone who'll tell them, "I know
what the Truth is, the single Truth. Everyone else we'll eliminate so they
won't interfere with our building of the ideal".
In my opinion,
a decisive factor in making pluralism and democracy compatible is the attitude
of the masses towards extremist, monistic parties, whether of the right or the
left. It is these parties that are especially dangerous at times of crises,
projecting an air of knowing the only way out and promising success if given
unlimited power, with at least a temporary ban placed on other parties. If the
political culture of the nation can resist the siren-like calls of the extremists,
then pluralism is compatible with extensive democracy. England did not succumb
to the temptation of an authoritarian regime during the Second World War, and
nor did Israel after more than forty years of extremely precarious existence.
In many
countries the conflict between pluralism and democracy was resolved in a very
painful fashion. We know of the German tragedy when, during the Great
Depression, the democracy of the Weimar Republic collapsed under the weight of
an insufficiently mature political culture - the majority of the Germans voted
for either Nazis or Communists.
West German
President, Richard von Weitzaker, in a speech on May 24, 1989, commemorating
the fortieth anniversary of the establishment of the Federal Republic, said
that in his country " the present generation of policy makers is made up
of people who learned from history. This generation understands that the
tragedy of the Weimar was not that it produced too many extremists too fast,
but that for far too long it had too few democrats."[21]
The
instability of many Latin American countries (or of Iran under the Shah), is
rooted primarily in the conflict between pluralism and democracy, which is often resolved in favor of democracy
bordering on ochlocracy. Democracy in
these countries is highly developed, what with
wide popular participation in elections, demonstrations, strikes, etc.
At the same time, the Latin American leaders realize the dangers posed by
extremist parties, and suppress them. The membership of the extremist parties
is either forced to go underground or
stay abroad. A ban on these parties is accompanied by various repressive
measures against the liberals, who disapprove of these curbs on freedom.
It was perhaps
Russia's tragedy that the February Revolution brought about a mass
participation in politics and a sudden rise of many parties, some of them quite
radical. The strains of the World War I and the country's political immaturity
worked to the advantage of extremist forces. The losers could accuse Marxists,
Jews, various external enemies-whoever they cared to-of condemning Russia to
misery, but we should not forget that it was not the October Revolution, but
the Russian Civil War, in which people had the choice to support either side,
that finally established the new regime.
I think that
Russia does not have deep pluralistic roots. A contemporaneous introduction of
democracy and pluralism there may be counterproductive, and result in the
destruction of pluralism and the formation of a new type of dictatorship.
Thus, I believe
that it is not in the least pedantic to insist on the difference between
pluralism and democracy. These concepts are not synonymous, and under certain
conditions they conflict with one another. What does Russia really need more -
democracy or pluralism? Which would it sacrifice if forced to make a choice?
I reckon that
what Russia needs above all is pluralism. Pluralism creates a diversity of
opinions, offers the opportunity to balance competing positions, and
effectively replace obsolete viewpoints with new ones. Does all this negate
democracy? Not at all. Only at the beginning it is, as it were, a limited,
"censored" democracy, with the franchise restricted to those meet
age, property, or residential requirements. As the country develops and the
people become more experienced and more competent, democracy also develops and
broadens.
I believe that
resolving the conflict between pluralism and democracy by suppressing pluralism
is fraught with many dangers. May be I am wrong, and the introduction of a so-called
"restricted democracy" is more effective. I can only fall back on the
example of England, the motherland of Western political freedoms. The political
history of England after the Glorious Revolution was primarily one of
developing pluralism - the initial institutionalization of the loyal opposition
was followed by the creation of a two-party system of the Tories and the Whigs.
All kinds of views were allowed in England, and it served as a refuge for many
foreign radicals - Karl Marx and Mikhail Bakunin, an anarchist, spent a greater
part of their active lives there. Democracy in England was limited: the
franchise was restricted not only on the basis of voting age, but also that of sex, property status, literacy,
and so on. Let us not forget that even in the middle of the last century the
great majority of the British population did not have voting rights. Workers
were granted voting rights about a hundred years ago, in the 1870s, and women
received them only after the First World War.
So, I believe that
what a country needs for development is primarily pluralism. I am not opposed
to democratization, but I prefer a very gradual one. Democracy is not a state,
it is a process that lasts a long time and takes many years to mature.
An attempt to establish democracy with one stroke where the people are not
ready for it, is counterproductive. If my concept of societal
multidimensionality is valid, then It
would seem that, instead of the usual
arguments over whether a democratic or an authoritarian regime is better for a
given country, it would better to consider another alternative: the creation of
an elitist pluralistic society as an intermediate stage on the road to a
developed free society. Maybe, one should start at a still earlier stage that
has the potential to evolve into this kind of
limited pluralistic society.
I believe there are important groups in the
U.S.S.R. that can accept pluralism. Let us say, for the sake of argument, that
there are three broad strata in the Soviet society today: intellectuals involved in arts and sciences;
professionals who by and large have scholarly degrees and who are employed as
hospital doctors, factory engineers, school and college teachers, or who are
employees of the party or the government bureaucracy; and manual laborers: industrial workers and peasants. I would
guess that the strength of dedication to the pluralistic ideals diminishes as
we move from the first group to the last.
I can easily
anticipate opposition to my views concerning the wisdom of limiting democracy
in certain countries. We do, after all,
live in the twentieth century, and the populace of many places can participate
in decision making, or at least has the formal right to vote. The demand to
limit participation could set off a wave of popular indignation. But if this
demand is restricted to those countries where the population is virtually
barred from national decision making, then the real inclusion of even a small stratum into this process can be considered
a step in the right direction, and one that might muffle the righteous anger of
the dispossessed. This anger will be virtually silenced if we further admit
that limited democracy at the national level can be coupled with the
inclusionary strategy at the local level[22].
My call for a
limited democracy in the Soviet Union might also give rise to an erroneous
impression that I look down upon the Russian people, or even insult them with
my pessimism concerning their abilities to pronounce upon national problems. I
look at this issue very differently. By calling for a slow process of
democratization in the Soviet Union, for the step-by-step inclusion of ever
greater numbers of people in national decision making, I express my faith in
the ultimate possibility of democratic rule in Russia. Haste in this matter can
overexcite the masses and plunge the country into anarchy, to which the
authorities are likely to respond with a more rigid autocracy, or even wide
spread violence. I am not at all sure that the liberals, who profess their
sincere love for the Russian people and express confidence in their readiness
to participate in national decision making, can really bring happiness to the
nation. In the last analysis, it is those who believe in the possibility of an
eventual triumph of democracy in Russia, and who now see the first tender
shoots of this process, who can do more actual good for the Russian people than
can the liberals, despite their good intentions.
Openness in the Soviet Union
In this
section I want to look closely at the issue of openness of Soviet society. For now I am interested only
in external openness, that is, in
Soviet relations with other countries, primarily with democratic ones, and
among them first and foremost, the
United States. The issue of Soviet internal openness needs special examination, which I will undertake
in subsequent chapters.
When today we
speak of the countries belonging to the First, Second, or Third World, we use
their GNP as our major criterion of classification. The exceptions are
well-known emirates of the Persian Gulf, though scoring high on the GNP per
capita index, are still grouped among the Third World nations - but for our
purposes they can be safely ignored.
I accept this
classification as fundamental, but want to add two more. The first is based on
the nations' degree of openness. One can distinguish between a one-sided
and a two-sided openness, and openness as regards inputs and outputs. By one-sided
openness of outputs I mean expansionism, a policy of conquest. By one-sided
openness of inputs I mean the attractiveness of a given country to outside
conquerors.
By two-sided
openness I mean exchanges between a given country and other countries that involve people, information, commodities,
services, money. It is this kind of openness which the present section is
mainly about.
Nations
interact over time, and whatever is true of their interactions in the
short-term, may not necessarily hold over the long haul.
My
classification only partly overlaps with the one based on the GNP. In the Third
World, there is a spectrum of countries of varying degrees of openness, from
India to present-day Iran. The main
difference between the one-party states of the Second World (Albania, the
U.S.S.R., Poland, Hungary,Yugoslavia) also seems to lie in their degree of
openness.
The First World countries also differ with
respect to openness, be it in their immigration or trade policies. Democracy
presupposes openness, but openness does not presuppose democracy. Spain under
Franco was an authoritarian, yet, to a great extent, an open country. Western
democracies do not erect barriers like the Great Chinese Wall or even a
"Small" Berlin Wall, but the
forces behind isolationism in some of them should not be underestimated
(remember the Monroe Doctrine).
The state's
openness has a bearing on its compatibility with other states. Let us roughly
divide all nations into two groups: democratic and autocratic. It seems that
the most compatible countries are democracies: in the last hundred years, they
have not fought each other. The most incompatible countries are large
autocracies, mainly because they have conflicting expansionist interests.
Relations between democracies and autocracies are more complicated. Long-term
stable interactions seem to be
impossible because they have different goals and means of development. The
short-term and mid-term relations between these two groups of countries can be
stable, depending on the state of
relations between autocracies. Thus, The US may enjoy a measure of
detente with China because of Beijing's bitter feud with Moscow.
The second
classification I want to propose is based on the degree of governmental control
of national resources. On the edges of the spectrum it is theoretically
possible to have a completely free society and a completely totalitarian one.
By this classification, the Soviet Union comes close to a totalitarian state:
the government there almost totally owns all commodities, natural resources,
information, and people. It also totally controls all the inputs (imports) and
outputs (exports) of the system, whether they are related to commodities,
information, or people.
Bringing all
three classifications together, I want to discuss some problems concerning the
two-sided openness of the Soviet Union. What does the Soviet Union want from
other countries? Do they agree to satisfy Soviet desires? What are these
countries willing to receive in exchange from the Soviet Union? What does the Soviet Union want to give in
exchange?
I will try to
provide some partial answers to these questions. The answers have not been
arranged according to the importance of the questions, but rather by the
category of inputs-outputs: people, information, commodities (services). All
answers are related mainly to Brezhnev's time.
Inputs.
People. The Soviet Union has no problems with
immigration: the quality of life in the U.S.S.R. does not encourage people to
emigrate there.
The Soviet
Union is interested in having students from Western and Third World countries
to come and study for several years. Because there is a shortage of labor, the
Soviet Union is also anxious to 'import' foreign workers.
The Soviet
authorities have a long-term interest in the visits of Western scholars from
whom they can borrow new scientific and technological ideas (for details, see
the subsection "Information"). Russian hospitality helps to encourage
such visits, but other obstacles intrude: many Soviet research centers are
obsolete or off-limits to foreigners; Soviet authorities are afraid of the
penetration of Western ideology. Conversely,
Western scholars who cherish the ideals of freedom often refuse to visit
the Soviet Union.
Soviet leaders
are of two minds respecting foreign tourism in the U.S.S.R.: on the one hand,
it brings in hard currency, and increases the number of admirers of the Soviet
Union (a brief visit spent in viewing historical monuments and cultural events
inspires tourists to think it's a great country). On the other hand, an
expansion of tourism requires considerable investment in the service sector, which, as I show in the
discussion concerning the export of nondurable consumer goods, the authorities
are averse to undertake. Besides,
foreign tourists can be a bad influence on the natives, (for example,, tourists
accustomed to Western nightlife sometimes ask for prostitutes) and it is
difficult for the authorities to operate with a double standard concerning their own citizens and foreigners.
Information. While extremely hostile to any
penetration of Western ideology, the U.S.S.R. generally welcomes the import of
Western scientific and technological information. Most of all, the Soviet Union
is interested in pioneering scientific ideas, preferably those with proven
military applications. The number of scholars in the U.S.S.R. is comparable to that
in the USA, but Soviet scholars generate few pioneering ideas - a fact borne
out by a small number of Soviet Nobel Prizes winners. The reasons lie deep
within the system. While pioneering paradigms anywhere often face opposition
from the scientific establishment, a pluralistic ideology backed up by a
multiplicity of financing sources and the international academic 'safeguards,' can help prevent the
killing of new ideas. In the U.S.S.R., a new idea without a demonstrable
practicality can be easily stopped by a bureaucratic system of allocation of
resources for R&D, and by an ideological climate in which the innovation
can be labeled a deviation from Marxism (for example, the cases of cybernetics,
genetics, etc.).
The Soviet
Union is interested in importing new technologies, particularly of a military
nature. (See section Dilemma in the
Productoin of Goods versus the Development of New Technologies in chapter
5).
The Soviet
Union is also interested in
importing new scientific ideas
either because the existing system, with its ideological climate and financing
mechanism, does not permit a successful research and development effort, or
because it does not have enough resources for current military needs and the
development of heavy industry.
Naturally, the
Soviet Union wants to separate the importation of scientific and technological
ideas from the penetration of Western ideology. That is why the Soviet Union is
more interested in importing publications and patent information than in the exchange of scholars.
Unfortunately for Soviet authorities, research and development are performed by
people, and contacts among them play a crucial role in the field.
Commodities.
For a long time after industrialization, the Soviet Union was not
interested in sustained importation of goods from non-socialist countries
because of its tendency toward isolationism. In addition, the Soviet Union did
not have the means to import a great deal from these countries due to the lack
of hard currency reserves; the bulk of
its foreign currency receipts comes from the sale of gold and oil.
The Soviet
Union can try to open the country more to commodities by increasing foreign
investments. These investments can be used to expand the production of raw
materials ( the reader will recall the debates in the early 1970s concerning
the wisdom of American investments in oil and liquid gas in Siberia, and
Japanese investments in the coal and timber industries) and industrial goods ( for example, a truck factory
built by Ford on the river Kama in the mid 1970s). The Soviet Union, by
exporting raw materials and commodities manufactured on the capacities financed
(and sometimes installed) by the West, could then pay back the principal and
interest.
Such methods
of increasing the openness of the Soviet Union toward inputs from the West are,
however, limited by the degree of compatibility of countries belonging to
different camps. The absence of guarantees from the Soviet Union that
long-range contracts will be honored makes Western investments in this country
vulnerable. The military orientation of the Soviet Union is another obstacle to
investment. Imagine the following scenario. A Western firm expresses its
willingness to invest in a new Soviet factory for the production of trucks. The
principal and interest could be
partially paid off by a certain portion of the output of trucks. These trucks
can be passed on by the Western firm to the Oriental neighbors of the Soviet
Union. But this firm has to have a
guarantee of high quality products. One of the conditions that will allow this
guarantee is a systematic control of the technology, which was developed by the
Western firm. This, in turn, requires involvement in the managerial body by a
representative of the Western firm. But the Soviet authorities cannot agree to
such a requirement for a very simple reason: the factory for truck
production will also be involved in the
production of military goods. It will have not only a plan for wartime, that
is, the so-called mobilizatsyonnyj plan, but it will also be involved in
peacetime production of goods for the army, along with all the other car and
truck factories. But to allow a foreigner to be a manager in a Soviet plant and
to have access to extra classified information is impossible. . .
Output.
People. The most difficult problem is to open
the U.S.S.R. to an outflow of people, by which I mainly mean emigration. An
expansionist country has many reasons to consider emigration as negative: in
war, emigres strengthen the enemy, though, of course, they also may be
potentially useful as fifth columns in occupied territories.
Russia has a
long history of hostility to emigrants. Over 130 years ago Aleksandr Herzen, a
Russian writer and revolutionary, in comparing Europe and Russia wrote:
"In Europe a man who lives abroad has
never been considered a criminal, nor one who emigrates to America a
traitor"[23].
The Soviet
Union has had periods when, for different reasons, a limited emigration was
allowed. But first a few words about 'compulsory emigration.'
Soon after the
October Revolution the severest punishment for a Soviet communist was exile from the world's first communist
country - Trotsky's exile was regarded as such a punishment. Later, under
Stalin, 'undesirable people' were not exiled - they were exterminated within
the country. Not until the 1970s did
the Soviet Union return to Lenin's practice of compulsory emigration (for example, Aleksandr I. Solzhenitsyn and
dissidents exchanged for Soviet spies and a communist leader). At the same time
Soviet leaders practiced 'semicompulsory emigration.' Dissidents whom the government for one reason or another is
afraid to isolate within the country (that is, keep them in a prison, labor
camp, or psychiatric clinic) were offered a choice: West or East (Siberia); they
chose the West.
Voluntary
emigration was permitted in limited numbers in the 1920s and in the 1970s and
1980s. The people who emigrated voluntarily
were mainly those who did not have a historical homeland in the Soviet
Union: Jews and Germans. But these spurts of emigration, as I have mentioned
before, were contrary to the aspirations of the leaders.
Long business
trips for Soviet professionals and education for Soviet students in Western
countries were also inconvenient for Soviet leaders; they were afraid these
people would either defect or return with an undesirable ideology. Relatively
short trips to the West ( several months) by professionals were more convenient for Soviet authorities,
who they were anxious to acquire Western scientific and technological
information. But there were many obstacles to this method of acquiring
information, both political and financial (the shortage of hard currency).
Also, a business trip to the West is a privilege and a reward for a Soviet
scholar (it is possible for him to enjoy the life of a free society and to buy
consumer goods much cheaper than in the
Soviet Union). An added note here is that the political loyalty of the traveler
and his devotion to the chief of the organization where he worked were
important conditions in gaining
permission to go abroad. All this demonstrates why genuine scholars were
seldom permitted to visit their colleagues in the West: such trips were the
privilege of mediocre scholars. The bureaucrats try to find a respectable
excuse for this. One of the former chiefs of the Foreign Relations Department
of the Central Mathematical Economic Institute of the Academy of Sciences of
the U.S.S.R. explained to me the unofficial position on business trips by
Soviet scholars to the West. "Bad scholars," he said, "do not
deserve this trip because they will not understand what the Western scholars
are doing. It is too dangerous to send good scholars abroad because they can
pass on their colleagues' great ideas. The best way is to send abroad mediocre
scholars: they can understand the activities of Western scholars and cannot
inform them of new ideas."
Mass tourism
from the Soviet Union to Western countries and to the Third World has been
limited for ideological and economic reasons.
Information. The Soviet Union is eager to export
information if it bolsters its national image. The U.S.S.R. spends a great
amount of money to export propaganda through radio and print medium,
particularly to the propaganda aimed at the millions of refugees from the U.S.S.R.
(after the Revolution and, especially, after World War II). The Soviet Union
has lost considerable prestige in the communist movement, and has weakened this
movement (by exposing Stalin, invading Hungary and Czechoslovakia, etc.). It
tries to compensate for this by attracting former Soviet citizens especially if
they have nostalgic feelings.
The Soviet
Union did not allow the output of any information, by any means, concerning the
true situation in the country. The enormous development of the system of classified
information was also an attempt to disguise the country's backwardness, but it
causes problems as well. It bureaucracy prevents the passing of successful
technologies from the military to the
civilians. I think that many military technologies, not classified in the West,
are super-classified in the Soviet Union and cannot be used in other
industries. The Soviet leaders understand this. To the best of my knowledge,
Aleksey N. Kosygin, when he was chairman of the Council of Ministries of the
U.S.S.R., tried to improve this situation; but the bureaucracy was stronger
than he was.
Commodities. The Soviet Union is one of the chief
exporters of weapons to the Third World (and also to terrorists in various
countries). The export of modern weapons is the best method by which to
subjugate countries that are dependent on weapons. It requires the presence of
qualified Soviet consultants, spare
parts purchased from the U.S.S.R., training in the Soviet Union, and so forth.
The export of
weapons to the Third World is accompanied by the export of Soviet industrial
goods. These countries, being in the orbit of the Soviet Union, do not have the
opportunity to trade with the West, and therefore have to buy Soviet goods. The
Soviet Union also stimulates these countries to buy its commodities by loans
with low interest rates.
Let us now
consider the factors that limit trade between the Soviet Union and the West.
These countries do not buy Soviet weapons, which the Soviet Union would not
sell to them anyway. So any trade between the Soviet Union and the West is
strictly nonmilitary.
Why, then, can the Soviet Union extend not
"peaceful" exports? I think a major obstacle was its expansionist
policy, as mentioned earlier. Let me be more specific. An increase in the production
of nondurable consumer goods
requires the development of agriculture and light industry. In turn,
this development requires more investment. But the limited money available for
investment is used for other industries important for expansionism. Moreover,
most equipment in agriculture and light industry can't be converted to the
production of military goods; the Soviet leaders prefer to develop industries that can be easily converted.
(Obstacles to the export of Soviet durable consumer goods will be
discussed later, under the subject 'industrial commodities.')
Now let us
look at the possibilities for export from the other edge of the production
system - natural resources. The Soviet Union has vast reserves of mineral
resources and timber. However, these are difficult to obtain because they are
located in remote areas where transportation and communication is not yet
sufficiently developed. The Soviet Union needs large investments to develop
these resources and expected to get the money from the West. But even if the
U.S.S.R. decides to develop these new areas of natural resources itself and to
export them to the West, there will be problems. Such export could give the
U.S.S.R. a key to the Western economies, with all the consequences that follow
from dependency on the Soviet Union. The oil embargo by a group of autocratic
countries in the 1970s makes the danger clear. The gas pipeline from the U.S.S.R. to Western Europe's is a
similar situation.
The
possibility of exporting capital goods is also limited. On the one hand,
the export of these commodities can be profitable for the U.S.S.R. because it
can produce them on capacities easily convertible to military needs; on the
other hand, the volume of import of these goods cannot be dangerous for the Western
countries.
The major
obstacle to increasing the export of industrial goods is their low quality.
There are many reasons for this,
particularly the Soviet philosophy of planning based on the idea of continuous physical growth. To promote this
growth, managers have to violate technological rules and reduce quality.[24]
The military orientation of the country is another cause of the low
quality of industrial goods. Quality is characterized by many criteria,
including longevity of the product. From the military point of view, tanks,
airplanes, trucks, and so on do not have to last long - probably only several
months in wartime. Therefore, it is not reasonable to spend extra resources to
increase the longevity of military implements. However, in the peacetime it is
important to produce tractors, airplanes, cars, trucks, and so on that will
last a long time. But this requires additional investment because the factories
producing these goods are oriented to the production of corresponding military
goods.
Thus, in order
to increase the quality of industrial
goods, the U.S.S.R. would require a reconceptualization of the whole attitude
to the performance principles of the Soviet system: in particular, the
aspirations of the leaders to increase the output by any means, the orientation
of the country to military needs, and so on, must be changed.
The Soviet Union, continuing the Russian
tradition, grows mainly by expansion. As long as the Soviet Union follows this
policy it will seek closedness-autarchy. Tactical decisions determine to what
extent the country will be open. The Soviet Union under Stalin is the best
example of this. When Stalin decided on rapid industrialization, he established
friendly relations with the West for a short period; without Western equipment
and professionals he could not achieve his goals. It is interesting to note
that at this time Peter the Great was Stalin's hero. As industrialization in
the rough was finished, Stalin closed the country; Ivan the Terrible became his
hero.
Brezhnev declared
at the beginning of the 1970s that the relationship between the USA and the
U.S.S.R. has to be based on more openness and that this policy has to become
irreversible. But this declaration is only a good wish. The Soviet autocratic
regime, and its expansionist policy, did not permit the opening of the country
to the extent that the openness could become irreversible. This regime opens
the country only to the extent that openness is reversible at any time.
Rejection of
expansionism as a leading policy is a necessary condition for the openness of
the country, which is in its turn a long - lasting factor for development of
the country. Certainly this condition is not sufficient for growth. One can
easily imagine an opposite situation when rejection of the policy of expanding
the empire, and moreover the rejection
of the empire itself, might bring economic stagnation for the country.
Such situations are linked with the introduction of fundamentalism and
isolation of the country (this is Solzhenitsyn's suggestion).
The
maintenance in the U.S.S.R. of extraverted values and the striving for growth
could be compatible with the openness of the country. Such a concept is
consistent with the country's security,
but not with expansionism. Certainly, openness makes the country dependent on
other countries and less secure. But because other countries also are becoming
dependent on the given country, under a certain level of mutual dependence a
situation can be reached where each of these countries is secure.
Openness
and Pluralism: Contemporary
History
It we look at
the foreign policy of different countries or of one country at different times,
we will see that there are alternatives between requirements for openness of
the interacting countries and for a particular country's pluralization. Let us consider this based on an analysis of
Soviet-American relations in the period from 1960 to 1980.
The attitude of the Soviet leaders to the
problem of openness-pluralism at the end of the 1960s may be determined in the
following way. At that time, Soviet
leaders understood that liberalization of the country would be dangerous:
among other things it would increase political tensions, and diminish the role
of the Communist party. Many leaders
remembered well the bitterness of Stalin's time and were afraid to revive
it. Under these conditions domestic
problems, such as the growing need for grain and modern military technology,
could be solved by improving relations with the West. (Buying grain and military technology from the West can only help
to plug the holes in the old system). The increased openness of the U.S.S.R.
was the sacrifice Soviet leaders made for the improvement of the relations
with the USA. (The American
government's tolerance of the absence of pluralism in the U.S.S.R. was used by
Soviet leaders in their subsequent struggles with dissidents). Under Stalin dissidents (even potential
dissidents) disappeared without a trace.
Under Khrushchev the dissident movement had not yet developed: people
believed in the possibility that the country might be liberalized from
above. After Khrushchev was dismissed,
with the trials of Siniavsky and Daniel, the new leaders announced that they
were going to stop the liberal movement.
The dissident movement was the response. However, the need to open
the country required more flexibility from Soviet leaders in their dealing with
the dissidents. The leaders chose Lenin's tactic: they used a 'mixed strategy.'
Some dissidents were forcefully exiled to the West (for example,
Solzhenitsyn); some emigrated under the
pressure of exile to Siberia; others were put in prison, labor camps, or
psychiatric clinics. A number of the dissidents were seduced by the
authorities: they stopped their activities in exchange for an attractive job,
business trips to the West, and other appealing temptations.
By the end of
the 1960s the US was looking for new avenues for peaceful coexistence. There
were many reasons for this: the unpopular Vietnam war, the burden of armament,
and, in particular, the danger of an atomic war (at that time the Soviet Union
were considering a preventive atomic war against China). The American
government was searching for these new avenues as a way to open the Soviet
Union to Western information, commodities, professionals, and tourists, and in
return get Soviet scientific information, emigrants, professionals, tourists,
and raw materials. Democratization of the U.S.S.R., as expressed by the claim
to maintain human rights in the country,
was put aside. It seems that the authors of this policy decided that the
increased openness of the U.S.S.R. would eventually bring the country to
pluralism. No doubt the more open a country, the more the leaders are limited
in their antiliberal activities; they fear public opinion in the West. In turn,
public opinion in free societies is amplified by the voices of dissidents from
the U.S.S.R.. Visiting the U.S.S.R. and talking with dissidents, relatives, and
other reliable people permits those in the free societies to better understand
the Soviet regime and to see the necessity for its liberalization.
The power of
many religions consists in the promise of paradise in the afterlife; whether
this promise is upheld cannot be verified. The desire of people to believe in
this ideal is so strong that they agree to accept such a promise even with no
proof. The desire of many people to see a paradise on earth is also strong. These people are ready to believe that
paradise can be built on communist ideology. The Soviet Union declared that it
was the first communist nation in the world. A paradise on earth can be tested;
people can check its reality. Maintaining a closed country is the best way to
prevent friends and enemies of communism from exercising their curiosity to
check the construction of paradise. A
concession to closeness is the regulation governing the arrival and departure
of pilgrims who disseminate the "truth" among the people anxious to
have heaven on earth. The openness of
the U.S.S.R. to a great extent stipulated the destruction of the myth of a
paradise in that country.
A leading
American liberal, a man of great talent and irreproachable moral credentials,
told me that he became disappointed with the Soviet system in the mid -1960s
when he heard the voices from the inside, that is, the protests of the
dissidents. Until then, he thought that a virulently anticommunist Western
propaganda exaggerated the negative aspects of Soviet reality: if the situation
in the U.S.S.R. was as bad as the Western media made it out to be, the Soviet
people would have let the world know about it. (Similar benefits of doubt were
once also enjoyed by China). Now we have only two communist countries that are
completely closed to the Westerners, North Korea and Albania. Naturally, they
became the models for some leftist groups in the West.
If a country
is authoritarian, it can fairly easily shut itself off from the outside
world and, by coercion and persuasion,
suppress any protests that appear during the period of openness.
The Nixon and
Ford Administrations were visibly successful when the U.S.S.R. opened up. The
Carter administration continued the policy of detente, but focused its
attention on the problem of human rights. The Carter policy was not consistent.
(For example, such an open country with great elements of democracy as the
Shah's Iran, was severely criticized for violating human rights; at the same
time, the US established friendly relations with China, a closed, undemocratic country). Certainly,
the emergence of a liberalized Soviet Union will radically alter the world
situation. But even if one supposes that it is possible to liberalize a country
from the outside, the process will take
a long, long time. Moreover, we may reasonably assume that openness is a
necessary stage in this process.
In any case,
to maintain peace in the world it is necessary to have democratic regimes in
the major countries; outside attempts to democratize the authoritarian regimes
require sophisticated strategies. Elaboration of such strategies is made
difficult by the dynamic environment of
changing leadership and policies in both the West and the U.S.S.R..
The Soviet
Union reacted negatively to the human rights efforts of the Carter
administration, but because the Soviet leaders wanted to retain the benefits of
detente, they were patient. US verbal
attacks on the U.S.S.R. were not decisive. Possibly, the US policy of
vacillation encouraged the Soviet Union to invade Afganistan. Following the
invasion, the American policy changed radically, and Washington imposed a grain
embargo on the U.S.S.R., among other punitive measures. The Reagan
Administration escalated the confrontation. The Soviet authorities moved to
shut off the flow of information from the West, cut down on scientific
exchanges, and then took further antidemocratic steps by smashing the domestic
dissident and liberal movements.
The
confrontation became all the more visible after Yury V. Andropov established
himself as head of the party. Under him, an anti-American propaganda
intensified immensely. I would even go so far as to say that under Andropov the
level of anti-American propaganda reverted to the pre-Brezhnevian time, in the
sense that the United States once again was classified as Enemy Number One:
under Brezhnev, that 'honor' for all intents and purposes belonged to China.
Under Konstantin Chernenko, the situation remained largely unchanged.
A new period
in US-Soviet relations was inaugurated by Gorbachev, but this is a subject for
the chapters to follow.
Notes and References
1. J. Stalin, Voprosy Leninisma
(Moscow: Gospolitizdat, 1953) 618.
2. J.Stalin, O velikoj otechestvennoj
vojne Sovetskogo Soiuza (Moscow: Gospolitizdat,1950) 351.
3
Who is Gorbachev?
I do not claim
to have the last word about this complicated question but I feel a few considerations
are in order. To begin, let us examine the specific changes in the Soviet
system enacted under Gorbachev.
Changes in the Soviet System under
Gorbachev
Under
Gorbachev, the Soviet political system started to shift. A special effort has
been made to alter the political climate in the country and shatter the
communist ideology. At the same time, the economic system has undergone but
minor changes, in spite of the rather ambitious plans for transforming the
Soviet economy in the direction of a market that were proclaimed soon after
Gorbachev assumed the throne. In fact, the last few years are marked by a
steady deterioration of the economic well-being of the population. Testifying
to this are the numerous statements made in mid-1989 by such prominent Soviet
figures as Academician Leonid Abalkin, Boris Yeltsin, and others warning of the
possible outbursts of massive unrest with all the ensuing consequences if the
economic situation in the country does not improve within the next one to two
years.
With the current state of the country being
what it is (compared to the New Economic Policy (NEP) or to China), Gorbachev's
primary concern extended to the transformation of the political system that was
rejecting major reforms in the economy. In his own words, political reforms are
destined to pave the way for economic changes and should help the country
overcome the critical trends in its overall development. Still, the steady
deterioration of economic performance has threatened the changes that have taken
place in the political realm.
What actual
reforms as far as ideology and political structure of the Soviet Union have
taken place under Gorbachev, and how extensive is the transformation he has
initiated in the political system entrenched in the country?
First let us
take ideology. During Khrushchev's era tremendous progress was made in
disparaging communist ideology as a result of the denouncing the myth of
Stalin. But it seems that Khrushchev himself still believed in the potency of
communist ideology; in any case, during his reign and prior to Gorbachev,
ideology was not questioned in the official Soviet press. In search of Stalinism's roots, glasnost initiated under
Gorbachev opened the question of the ideology which could have and did lead to
this phenomenon. Particularly interesting in this respect is a series of
articles entitled "The Roots of Stalinism" appearing in four issues
(eleven to twelve 1988, one to two 1989) of a popular Soviet magazine Nauka
i Zhizn (Science and Life). The author is A. Tsypko, a Doctor of
Philosophy who is working (or who did work) in the apparatus of the Central
Committee (CC) of the CPSU. In these articles, Tsypko actually questions the
essence of communist ideology. For on the one hand, under the banner of class
struggle, it brings tremendous destruction to mankind in material as well as
spiritual realms, obliterating hard earned accomplishments. On the other hand,
this ideology being incapable of constructive activity, poses goals so
grandiose that any means of attaining are justified. These articles have made a
strong impression upon Soviet liberal intelligentsia and have become the
subject of much controversy.
With the
decline of communist ideology, there are signs of Russian chauvinist ideology
gaining popularity. Novel in this respect, compared to Stalin's time, is the
tolerance on the part of the authorities toward organizations openly professing
Russian chauvinism (such groups as "Pamiat" and its various
offshoots).
The church has
come to the fore over the course of glasnost, especially after the pompous
festivities in June 1989 commemorating
a thousand years of the christening of Russia. Church ideology has been widely
publicized. First and foremost, the absolute moral values (as opposed to the
relative communist morality) preached by the church have directly or indirectly
assumed the status of official acceptance.
But communist ideology is not the only aspect
that has been officially and explicitly attacked under Gorbachev.
All evidence
points to the fact that Gorbachev wishes to propel this idea by eliminating
Soviet ideocracy, that is, by doing away with the "tri-spiral"
hierarchy of management primarily by excluding the Communist party. Gorbachev's
statements at the nineteenth Party Conference regarding drastic reductions,
especially in the central party apparatus, with subsequent reallocation of
power to the local Soviets testify to his intentions. I mean Gorbachev's
decision to concentrate the power in the hands of the president of the country,
that is, the Chief of Supreme Soviet. Symbolizing this transformation is the
appointment of the president as the chief commander of the armed forces, a
position formerly held by the first secretary of the Central Committee.
Communist party remains, with the president as its first secretary. In case the
Congress of People's Deputies chooses not to elect the first secretary to the
position of the president, it should serve as a signal to the party that its
leader is unpopular with the people and should be replaced by the party; the
reverse is not stipulated. One indirect confirmation of the declining role of
the Communist party is the difficulty of finding people to fill various party
posts. Several provincial secretaries speaking at the May 1989 Plenum of the
Central Committee have mentioned vacancies in their apparatus and the
difficulty of filling them.
Elements of
pluralism have also cropped up under Gorbachev, manifesting themselves
primarily in the tolerance of open expression of one's disagreement with the
current state of affairs and the open criticism of the past. Criticism of
leaders, Gorbachev included, became possible, and occasionally even in the
official press. Although the bulk of criticism is still directed at the past,
the mere fact that the current leadership has been in power for over four years
makes contemporary criticism more and more realistic. Under Gorbachev, progress
has been made in the institutionalization of pluralism. The official Soviet
press has branched into journals and newspapers having diverse orientation, a
process especially conspicuous in literary publications. Khrushchev's period
gave rise to some diversity in the ideology professed by various journal's (Novyj
Mir versus Octiabr in particular) but in the years that followed
ideology was again subjected to unification for quite some time. In the course
of glasnost, the rift between liberal journals such as Ogonyek, Znamia,
and Octiabr and strongly chauvinistic journals like Nash Sovremennik,
Molodaia Gvardiia, and Moskva has come into sharp focus; it seems
Novyj Mir follows a moderate nationalistic trend (subjecting the current
state of things to extremely strong criticism). Keeping in mind the revered
status traditionally enjoyed by the printed word and literature in particular
in Russia, this variety of literary publications is remarkable, since they form
what could be called the epicenters of the development of different political
trends. Similar diversity, although more restricted, has surfaced among major
official Soviet newspapers. Of course, pluralism in this category is rather
limited, for all major newspapers lack independence and are completely
subordinated to their respective bodies of power (the chief editors of
newspapers are all appointed from above, newspapers' financial dealings are
completely spelled out, etc.); all major issues are still subject to a rigid
censorship by the party apparatus. The creation of independent publishing
houses under the banner of a cooperative enterprise was outlawed by decree that
declared this kind of cooperatives illegal.
A more
significant development of pluralism occurred with the formation of the so
called informal societies (neformaly). These groups meet to discuss
various contemporary issues, and they take active measures (by means of
demonstrations, for instance) to call the attention of the public and those in
power to their grievances.
Institutionalization
of a multiparty system in the U.S.S.R. is still very remote. Noteworthy in this respect is a statement made by Vadim
Medvedev, the member of the Politburo in charge of ideology, at a press
conference in May of 1989. The introduction of a multiparty system in the
Soviet Union is mentioned as a meaningful subject for discussion.
Gorbachev's
impact on another aspect of society must be examined: democracy per se. Under
Gorbachev masses have really gained greater access to the decision-making
mechanism. In 1989 the public participated, although via many intermediaries,
in the election of the country's president and of the Supreme Soviet of the U.S.S.R.
Recent elections have incited the masses to greater activity, since for the
first time they were able to discuss their candidates, usually numbering more
than one. Mass involvement surfaced especially prominently in voting against
those in power even though they might have been the only candidate on the
ballot.
Another
dimension of society that must be examined is the separation of power. I have
already noted one significant step currently in the making: the separation of
party and state, transforming the party into an ideological institution. In
addition, the greater role of both the Christian church as Islam points to a
rather bleak future for the Communist party. Naturally, party chiefs will not
concede their power easily. The party apparatus doggedly defends itself against
Gorbachev's encroachments. A friend of mine in Moscow has made an interesting
observation to the effect that if previously the cooperation among party
functionaries was mostly 'vertical' and the conflict 'horizontal,' (since each
functionary was eager to please his boss, and competed with his peers for the
attention of the higher-ups) now, when the apparatus faces a single bitter
enemy, cooperation and mutual help within it have become universal. My friend
has observed this phenomenon both at the level of regional party secretaries
and district party secretaries in big cities.
Gorbachev
maneuvers to appease the party. This is chiefly the result of his personal
power games. It was precisely party support that Gorbachev needed in order to
be elected by the rather conservative Congress of People's Deputies. The Plenum
of the Central Committee of the CPSU, which met before the elections, voted to
support Gorbachev's exclusive candidacy for the post of president. This
decision obligates all members of the party to vote for Gorbachev (with party
members comprising about 87 percent of all the deputies).
But I do not
want to oversimplify the situation by reducing Gorbachev's relations with the
party only to his power games. Gorbachev simply cannot ignore the functional
role of the party in today's institutionally backward Soviet economy. When
economic managers operate without adequate monetary incentives, other forms of
control are brought to bear upon them: the failure to fulfill the plan may
result in punishment of various degrees of severity, from party reprimand to
expulsion.
Also, because
the Soviet Union lacks administrative economic bodies that coordinate the
activities of enterprises belonging to different and, especially, All-Union ministries
within a given territorial unit, the party steps into the breach to perform the
coordinating mission ( for more details, see chapter's 6 section on "The
Double Hierarchy of the Soviet System of Governance.")
Gorbachev's
attacks on the party have noticeably weakened its role in the economy. But no
alternative institutions have appeared
that could accomplish through economic suasion the functions that the party
used to accomplish coercively. In view of the worsening economic situation
exacerbated by political conflicts, and the enormous problems of building new
economic institutions, it cannot be ruled out that Gorbachev would be forced to
make some concessions to the party apparatus, relieve the pressure being put
upon now, and even enhance its role somewhat.
The
postponement of local elections from the fall of 1989 to the spring of 1990 can
be viewed as a concession to the party chiefs: in the spring 1989 elections of
peoples' deputies, the voters in some parts of the country voted against
regional party chiefs even when they were the only candidates on the ballot.
(Especially blatant were the elections in Leningrad, when Iury Soloviev, an
alternate member of the Politburo, and first secretary of the Leningrad
Province Committee of the party, was voted out). At the May 1989 Plenum of the
Central Committee which followed the elections to the Congress of of People's
Deputies, a number of provincial secretaries
expressed apprehension concerning the upcoming fall 1989 elections to
the local Soviets. Many of them feared that they would not be elected to the
local Soviets, and the ensuing loss of their positions as secretaries. New
rules stipulate that a secretary of a province who is not elected to the post
of chief of the local Soviet has to give up his post.
One other
point exists in support of my hypothesis that Gorbachev is making certain
concessions to the party. Gorbachev initiated a well-known campaign against
corruption. Trials were fueled (before, during, and after) by much propaganda
in mass media and involved rather highly placed officials in the party and the
government. Suddenly, in June of 1989 the press announced that one, Smirnov,
the second secretary of the Communist party of Moldavia, was unjustly convicted
on bribery charges and is now free; a major article by Olga Chaikovskaia in the
Literaturnaia Gazeta questioned the lawfulness of the arrest of
Churbanov, Brezhnev's son-in-law, who is serving a sentence for bribery.
Perhaps these facts are a testimony to certain concessions made by Gorbachev to
the conservative fraction of the party.
Separation of
judicial and executive branches should, in principle, be promoted by the
changes in the charter of the Supreme Soviet of the U.S.S.R., a body being
transformed into a continuously working institution. It is hard to say at this
point what all these changes will bring. The fact that the Committee of the
Supreme Soviet must ratify government appointments (in the executive branch)
should, in theory, be conducive to the separation of power. At the same time,
it is still unclear how for the membership of this Committee is subject to
manipulation by the party apparatus, which can thus maintain its supreme power
from behind the scene. Still, Gorbachev's general intent to transfer the bulk
of the managerial power from the party to the Soviet apparatus suggests that
these committees are independent from the party and will eventually assume its
role. Indeed, confirmation of all appointments to the executive branch was
previously carried out by the apparatus of the Central Committee.
The problem of
ensuring independence of judicial bodies from the party was raised many times,
but I know of no real measures enacted to serve this cause.
Openness.
Under
Gorbachev, significant changes have taken place as far as openness is
concerned.
Let us first
consider openness within the country. Migration within the country has
basically remained the same: there is an internal passport regime and limited
inflow to the cities.
Glasnost has
had a great impact upon the openness of information about the country's
past, its present political situation and debates about its future. As far as
the level of secrecy in the areas of technological and economic data, leaders'
private lives, etc., there have not been any significant shifts, although these
issues are raised in the press.
Free exchange
of goods and services via market mechanisms has gained somewhat as a result of
private enterprises known as cooperatives: as of this writing, they employ
nearly two million people. But the number of cooperatives is still small, for
they are limited in their growth by the overall scarcity of resources (in
getting work space, equipment, supplies), fear of being expropriated, and so
on. The state moves from one extreme to the other in regulating private
businesses and cooperatives, sometimes giving incentives and sometimes imposing
severe limitations via high taxes, outlawing certain kinds of cooperatives,
etc. As a rule, the masses are hostile to private businessmen, thinking they
earn too much money: one of the demands of the striking miners in 1989 was the
closing down of cooperative ventures. There is a grain of truth in this
antagonism. U.S.S.R. today is characterized by extreme deficit and mixed
economy with the dominant role played by the state sector with its relatively
low prices on consumer goods. These circumstances encourage semi-legal and
illegal activity on the part of private enterprise. For instance, a restaurant
owner can buy large quantities of meat at state stores at low prices and sell
shish kebab at a high market price. Nevertheless, certain aspects of public
animosity toward private business are unjustified. The standard of living
enjoyed by private businessmen is much higher than that of the nation as a
whole, with the latter suffering from a steady deterioration in their economic
well-being. Antipathy toward private business also has its roots in the Russian
culture, in traditional Russian antagonism toward the rich, who were regarded
as vampires, exploiters, and speculators. The facts that active individuals
produce more; that,if there are many active individuals, their high
productivity will increase the size of the entire pie thus bettering everybody;
and that active individuals only consume a small share of the overall pie, are not
sufficient to convince the masses not to feel animosity toward these people.
Let us now
consider inflows and outflows from the outside.
Inflows"
to the U.S.S.R. There
has been a large increase in the inflow of foreigners into the Soviet Union.
Here, I speak not only of Western scholars and businessmen: in the last few
years, recent emigrants from the U.S.S.R. living in any Western country,
including Israel, have been allowed to visit the country without much problem
(with the exception of some former dissidents). Until recently, their travel
into the U.S.S.R. was unthinkable under any pretext. In some exceptional cases
which threatened to explode into international scandal, recent emigrants from
the Soviet Union were permitted to go back (as with S. Lerner attending her
mothers' funeral). The reasons for easing the restriction on travel into the
Soviet Union are many, not the least of which is the desire to acquire the
foreign currency so desperately needed by the country. I believe another reason
for easing the travel restrictions against former emigrants into the U.S.S.R.
is the desire on the part of the Soviet Union to have certain groups of people
in the West sympathetic to the country. For many years, these groups were
formed from the members of Western communist parties and their sympathizers.
These circles have been largely lost since the mid-1950s especially after the
denunciation of Stalin in 1956 and the suppression of the Hungarian revolution
that same year. In subsequent years, the Soviet Union tried, not without
success, to make up for these losses by creating international terrorism.
Gorbachev's new policy of closer international ties has forced the Soviet
government, at least to a considerable extent, to reject its support of
terrorism. Who is there in the West to lean upon? One reserve is the former
Soviet citizens now living abroad. Soviet leaders have been making passes at
them for quite a while. They made some progress in the 1930s and soon after the
end of World War II in their appeal to the Russians who fled abroad after the
October Revolution. But these people have grown old, while their children and
grandchildren have become largely assimilated. A policy of cajolement has been
tried on the Russians and, especially, the Ukrainians who fled to the West via
Germany after the war. But many of them collaborated with Hitler and they are
scared to visit the Soviet Union; also many of them are now old or have passed
away. With the Jewish emigration to Israel, or more precisely to the West, which
started in the beginning of 1970s more than three hundred thousand Jews have
left the Soviet Union. These people, who are typically young and middle aged,
emigrated legally, leaving close friends and relatives in the U.S.S.R. Being
deeply assimilated, they have, as a rule, brought over their Russian heritage
and maintain an interest in their former country. For this reason, this group
is of particular interest to the new Soviet leadership. Closer ties with this
group were officially announced in December, 1988 by a member of the Politburo,
Minister of Foreign Affairs Eduard Shevardnadze. No one can say for
certain when, how, for what purposes,
or even which of the new wave of emigrants will be used by the Soviets. But the
presence of a sufficiently large group of people sympathetic to the regime
provides candidates who, under proper circumstance, may extend favors to their
former homeland. Naturally, I do mean to say that every Soviet emigrant
visiting the Soviet Union is a potential spy. In fact, the majority, perhaps
the great majority, of emigrants visiting the U.S.S.R. come back reassured that
they have made the right decision in leaving the Soviet Union.
The flow of information
into the Soviet Union from the West has increased drastically over the course
of glasnost. Whereas before there was sufficient inflow of scientific and
technical information, materials concerned with social and political issues
have become much more accessible in the last few years. Jamming of Western
radio broadcasting in Russian (and other languages spoken in the Soviet Union)
which could be heard sporadically, has once again been suspended; this
pertains, for instance, to the Voice of America and the BBC. Jamming of Radio
Liberty, known for its sharp criticism of the Soviet system has been suspended
for the first time. It has become much easier to bring literature into the
Soviet Union, including political and religious literature.
Nothing as
drastic has taken place in the import of goods. In fact, the import of
consumer goods, especially manufactured goods, has fallen because of a lack of
hard currency (more on this below, in the discussion of the export of goods).
The U.S.S.R.
still lags in the importation of capital goods and in attracting Western firms
into joint ventures. Nonconvertability of the Soviet currency aside, the
problem is the payment that Western businessmen can expect to receive in
exchange for their goods.
Outflows
from the U.S.S.R. Let
us now look at openness as far as the outflows from the country. First of all,
emigration from the Soviet Union has increased drastically. Just as before it
is limited to a few nationalities-Jews, Germans, and Armenians. It seems at
this point that an emigration law that would apply to all people except those
having access to classified information, etc., is close at hand. If passed, the
law should not lead to a mass exodus from the country. Western countries have
rigid immigration quotas and basically only a small number of Soviet citizens
can gain access to the West. Moreover, by imposing classified status upon the
important positions, Soviet leaders can make sure that the most qualified
individuals remain in the country. Not too many people are capable of leaving
their classified job for unclassified work and then wait several years for the
right to apply for emigration.
Whereas
emigration has undergone a quantitative shift, temporary travel by Soviet
citizens has shifted qualitatively. For the first time, Soviet citizens, no
matter what their nationality, have been granted a real opportunity to visit
friends and relatives in the West, including Israel. All that is required is an
invitation from abroad. The processing of all the relevant documents has been
made much simpler (no longer are work references required, no approval by a district
Party Committee, etc.). Tens of thousands of Soviet citizens have thus been
able to visit the West. Of special note is the recently acquired opportunity
for gifted Soviet scholars (of any nationality) to visit their colleagues in
the West, provided they receive an invitation with all the expenses of their
stay in the West covered. Hundreds of scholars who have never been allowed to
go to the West in spite of many invitations have come here in recent months.
Certain
changes have taken place in the export of information from the Soviet Union.
Newspapers geared toward the West, Moscow News in particular, have
become rich in content, painting a very
vivid picture of the situation in the country. Non-conformist Soviet painters
have been given a chance to show and sell their work abroad. One should note a
much greater influx into the United States of various representatives of Soviet
culture (writers, poets, actors) who are of special interest to the Russian
speaking public, especially from the last wave of emigration. Oftentimes these
representatives of Soviet culture are called "paratroopers," since
their goal, whether intentional or not, is to stir feelings of nostalgia in
their former countrymen. By no means do I mean to insult Soviet cultural
figures visiting the West; most of them are decent people. I merely want to
note that many of them do not realize the sinfulness of their conduct and do
not repent; that is, they do not realize that a very natural temptation to
visit the West should not be justified by noble intentions once one has chosen
to participate in the "propaganda volley."
There have
been no significant changes in the export of goods from the U.S.S.R. Actual
revenues from exports have decreased as a result of a drop in oil prices, which
represents a major source of foreign currency.
What is our
overall verdict of Gorbachev's reforms? Presently I will try to answer this
difficult question, but consider that he has been in power longer than the term
of an American president. Franklin D. Roosevelt, faced with a very critical
situation in 1932, was able to turn the economy around in the first few years
of his presidency.
Following a
systems approach, we proceed by immersing the above question in a more general
problem. This will bring into relief the common features (invariants) of the
general and the specific and allow us to distinguish the peculiarities of the
problem at hand. Subsequently, in dealing with our initial question, we can
integrate the general and the specific aspects. In other words, the fusion of
the general and the particular should be avoided in the initial analysis of the
problem. It will be achieved when we integrate these features which were
revealed in our previous analysis. In our case, the general problem that
encompasses the Gorbachev question is the history of Russia.
Invariants of Russian History and the
Flexibility of Upholding Them
The history of
the Russian state, centered around Moscow for approximately the last seven
hundred years, starting with Ivan I (Ivan Kalita) and cotinuing to the present
(including Gorbachev's period), reveals at least two invariants: the first is autocracy
and the second is the empire. These two invariants of Russian
history have been preserved under various political modes known in the Marxist
literatures as feudalism, capitalism, and socialism. Feudal Peter I, bourgeois
liberal Nicholas II, and communist Vladimir I. Lenin all maintained an
autocratic imperial regime in Russia,
justifying their actions with very different slogans. Only briefly did
Russia betray its two traditions. This was the period that lasted for eight
months between February and November of 1917, when a bourgeois republic was
created in Russia and events could have led to a disintegration of the empire.
But Bolsheviks, headed by Lenin, were quick (almost immediately after the
October Revolution) to put Russia back upon its traditional course of autocracy
and empire.[25] In this sense, the October Revolution
was in fact a counterrevolution for it backtracked from the liberal gains
achieved by the February Revolution.[26]
The two
features of Russian history have been sustained by very different means under
various leaders. Some employed methods that gravitated toward tyranny while
others inclined toward liberalism. I want to repeat that the ideological
justification of the various methods is not so important. What is essential is
which of these methods were used by Russian leaders to preserve and strengthen
an autocratic imperial regime. From this perspective the spectrum of Russian
rulers includes tyrants such as Ivan the Terrible, Peter the Great, and Stalin
as well liberally inclined leaders such as Alexander II and Nicholas II. While
all of them strengthened an autocratic imperial state their methods varied
considerably. Ivan the Terrible, Peter the Great, and Stalin employed cruel
coercive ways. Alexander II and Nicholas II attempted to ease the pressure
exerted by authority.
Stalin took
the Russian tradition to an extreme. In its autocratic aspect his reign was not
original: his reign, just like that of Ivan the Terrible and Peter the Great,
turned into tyranny. But the imperial invariant took on a heretofore unseen and
grotesque scale. Not only did Stalin reannex parts of the Empire given up by
Lenin and drastically augment the Russian empire to the greatest size it has
ever known, but it seems that he aspired to make Russia the master of the world
and saw himself as the world sovereign.
Alexander II
abolished serfdom and instituted judicial reform. During his reign, Russia started
to rebuild its industry (for instance, metallurgy based on then modern
principles started to develop in Donbass). At the same time, Alexander did not
surrender an inch of land; in fact, he annexed Bessarabia, which had been lost
in 1855 after the Russian defeat in the Crimean War, as well as new lands in
the south of Russia and in the Far East. He cruelly suppressed the Polish
rebellion of 1863, demanding more severe punishment for the rebels than some of
his associates. Liberal reforms under Nicholas II were quite extensive. He went
as far as allowing the Duma (Parliament) to be formed, and allowing the
creation of a multiparty system, and he enlisted such outstanding statesmen as
Sergey U. Vitte and Petr A. Stolypin in his administration. Still, Nicholas maintained his right as a monarch
to be "the ruler of destinies" of the empire (some small territories
were lost after the defeat of Russia in the Russo-Japanese War of 1904-1905).
The majority of Russian rulers gravitated
toward one of the two extremes mentioned above. For example, Pavel I was closer
to the tyrant, while Alexander I was inclined toward liberalism for a
considerable part of his reign.
Autocracy, Empire and the Flexibility of
NEP
Very pertinent
to our discussion is the period of Soviet history known as New Economic Policy
(NEP). I claim that, during this period, an autocratic and imperial system
headed by Lenin was upheld and strengthened by diverse and flexible means.
Within the framework of this section I want to examine the NEP and its peculiar
features as well as the difference between that period and the present state of
Soviet Russia and China.
When the NEP was started, the great majority of
Russians (approximately 80 percent) lived in rural areas and worked in
agriculture. The village had its share of the semi-strong and strong peasants
known as seredniak and kulaks. These peasants still had faith in
the government. The equipment they used was rather primitive: the horse was the
draft animal and fertilizers were supplied from domestic animals and horses.
Under these conditions, the limiting factor in improving agricultural
productivity of peasants was the incentives to work. Therefore, a switch from prodrazverstka to prodnalog (from a surplus appropriation system to a
system of tax in kind) in the Soviet village in 1921 gave peasants a tremendous
opportunity to increase their output. Similar reforms were initiated in China
in the last decade.
A jump in
output in the Soviet countryside was accompanied by a rapidly mobilized private
trade, which allowed agricultural goods to be transported to the city. The
latter is due to the material foundation of trade and, even more importantly,
to the experienced individuals who still remained in the country. Allowing
small private enterprises considerably (although insufficiently) improved the
output of industrial goods needed in the rural and urban areas. The then-poorly
developed industrial sector alleviated leaders' fears that labor, equipment,
and materials would flow into the private sector.
Although the
adoption of the NEP dealt a severe blow to communist ideology (in fact, a number of communists even
committed suicide, especially sincere this ideology had espoused drastic
curtailment of private initiative and the abolition of a monetary system),
communist ideology in general still had a certain appeal to a large part of the
population. The era was marked by jubilant victors over the old system, with
their supremacy sealed by the victory in the civil war. All these factors
allowed a certain loosening of the ideological reigns, since political
opposition was knocked out.
As far as the
political system is concerned, the already rigid political structure created
prior to the NEP was tightened even further. The NEP period is surrounded by a
certain romantic haze. People think that along with economic liberalization,
the political screws were loosened as well, and various different points of
view were permitted in political life. This is incorrect. Such opinions emerge
from an inadequate understanding of the fact that the NEP was instituted at a
time when political tightening occurred parallel with economic liberalization.
Apparently, people apply certain stereotypes by which they associate economic
liberalization with political liberalization. I know of no instance when a
politically liberal system existed with a nonliberal economic system. But the
possibility of the reverse is well documented: it is the experience of Franco's
Spain as well as Yugoslavia and Portugal; it was also the experience of the
NEP.
In his report
to the lOth Party Congress (1921), Lenin introduced a sharp tightening of the
political structure along with liberalization in the economic sphere.
Right-wing parties had been banned earlier; now left-wing parties (Social
Revolutionaries, Mensheviks and others) were banned and, moreover, factions
within the only permissible party remaining, the Bolshevik party, were also
eliminated. The NEP saw the creation of a monolithic political structure.
Within limits, this political structure's development led to a total
atomization of society, that is, to the prohibition of any independently formed
organizations.[27]
The creation
of a rigid political structure under the NEP must not be confused with a rigid
ideological climate. Of course, such a political structure sharply limits freedom, but it still can permit some
ideological variety in art and science, debates and so on. But what is
important is that all these liberties are deprived of an institutionalized
basis and, therefore, can be easily liquidated when suitable.
Therefore,
irrespective of some ideological liberties and economic liberalization, the
creation of a rigid political structure is dangerous because it is predisposed
toward the appearance of a dictator, or even a tyrant. Once political power is
concentrated in the hands of one person, or even a small group of individuals,
and all forms of organized opposition are excluded, it is then difficult to do
anything at all to limit the power of the leadership.
Under the NEP,
a structure was created that determined to a great extent what was to happen
later politically, that is, the appearance of a system that featured one
omnipotent leader and that lacked controls over that leader's actions. I do not
want to say that the arrival of such a leader was completely determined or that
it was ineluctable. Soviet history could have turned out otherwise. But the
system created by Lenin and his followers was predisposed toward such a
leader's emergence. A more general question: why did they create such a system
in the first place? It occurred first and foremost because the system was from
its very beginning theocratic, religious, in nature, insofar as its leaders
knew the Truth. Once the Truth is known, why permit other alien truths to
abound? Why pose the question of checking the
validity of the Truth? It's only necessary in this case to conduct
inspections to monitor how directives are being implemented, that is, a
bureaucratic hypostasis of the Truth. But checking the implementation of
directives is something completely different from checking the extent to which
the directives themselves are any good. Under the NEP, the apparatus for
checking the validity of directives was liquidated. For such checking, an
independent opposition is needed, an opposition organized so that it can muster
the strength to develop a different opinion and contrast it to the existing
one.
Thus, the
first invariant of Russian history, namely autocracy, was not breached during
the NEP. The second aspect-the empire- was, to a large degree, also upheld.
During the Civil War and then during the NEP the former Russian empire had to
deal with strong separatist movements of various nationalities. These movements
were rather cruelly suppressed, and basically all the territories formerly
belonging to the Russian empire were preserved, except for the Western parts of
the Baltic region and Poland. I shall discuss this subject in more thoroughly
the chapter dealing with the Russian empire.
The present
day situation in the U.S.S.R. is completely different. The great majority of
the population does not work in agriculture: in 1987 the rural population was
only 34 percent of the U.S.S.R. total population, while only 22 percent (this
figure accounts for working individuals as well as their dependents) of the
total population worked in agriculture.[28] But the relative ratios of rural and
urban populations is not really the issue. In the last sixty years a stereotype
arose in many regions of the U.S.S.R., especially in Russia proper, that only a
fool stays in the village. Therefore, the stronger among the rural dwellers
have left the village. Today there are fewer men, and those remaining are
oftentimes the old, invalids, or alcoholics. But even those remaining in the
village have lost much of their faith in the government and they are
apprehensive when it comes to investing effort into enterprises promising
long-term rewards.
Also, Soviet
agriculture relies primarily on mechanized equipment, not horses. This
equipment is better suited for large-scale farming. But what is even more
crucial is that agricultural machinery is built to be easily convertible for
military use. In addition, modern-day technology calls for artificial
fertilizers, herbicides, etc., plus skill in applying them under the conditions
at hand.
At the present
time, the transfer of trade and light industry into private hands is difficult,
for it is requires that skilled labor, equipment, and materials flow into those
sectors, and away from the heavy industry that still tops the list of
priorities. The rechanneling of resources assumes the most grotesque shape
(bribes, theft, etc.), since all the reforms are taking place under the
conditions of extreme deficit. Also, many people are afraid to open a own
private business. There is no guarantee of keeping the business, because of the
possibility of its expropriation; in addition there is also the attitude of the
populace toward private enterprise, especially in Russia. The hostility of the
populace toward private businessmen-"vampires"-is an age-old Russian
tradition, easily revived after so many years of suppressing
private-entrepreneurial activity.
I have already
mentioned that the official ideology
has lost its vitality: people have simply lost faith in it.
So, the
present-day situation in the Soviet Union bears very little resemblance to the
period preceding the NEP. People,
production capacities, and agricultural technology have been severed at the
root. Encouraging private enterprise breeds fears that qualified personnel and
capital goods will be rechanneled from heavy industry into the private sector.
The great majority of the population has become disillusioned with leaders'
promises and with the official ideology. Separatist movements in the empire
that has grown in the course of the last seventy years have been actively
harassing the central authorities. All these factors call for an approach very
different from the one used to revive the country at the time of the NEP.
So, Who Is Gorbachev?
We can come to
at least two important conclusions in summing up our discussion of Russian
history: first, that two invariants have prevailed throughout Russia's seven
hundred year history: autocracy and empire; and second, that the ways of
upholding these two traditions varied: some gravitated toward despotism with
tyrannical leaders, while others inclined in the direction of liberalism with
almost liberal leaders.
I believe
these two conclusions are sufficient to answer, if only roughly, the question
"Who is Gorbachev?" I want to reformulate the question in the
following, up-front way. Is Gorbachev a leader who is trying to break the two
aforementioned invariants of Russian history and take Russia upon a course of
democratic development, liberating subordinated territories whose people seek
national autonomy? Or is Gorbachev a leader who seeks to preserve the
entrenched Russian autocratic imperial regime by employing more flexible
methods than have been employed in the past? I want to note that in speaking of
Gorbachev's policies regarding the invariants of Russian history, I mean not
his intentions but the actual institutions he has created. Of course, it is
hard to separate these two issues, and so I apologize to the reader for a
certain inconsistency: sometimes I speak of Gorbachev's intentions rather than
examining the actual institutional changes taking place.
Let me make
the question, "Who is Gorbachev?" more precise. Is not Gorbachev an
autocrat playing the role of a centrist leader using, up till now, a
mixed strategy in upholding the Russian tradition, with a certain emphasis upon
liberalism? The implementation of this policy has met with great obstacles.
Gorbachev's problems stem not just from the bureaucracy, which resists change,
but also from the exhaustion of the country, the traditional culture of the
Russian people, and a rather low cultural level of the current leadership and
their advisers.
Let me say a
few words regarding the cultural level of Soviet leaders, and of Gorbachev in
particular. Gorbachev was a law student at the Moscow State University. Most of
his student years belonged to Stalin's era, a period later marked by a campaign
against "cosmopolitanism" and the subsequent elimination or expulsion
from the law schools of what scholars there were left and an influx of Andrey Y.
Vyshinsky's stooges. Under the circumstances, education and training by an
activist of the Komsomol casts serious doubt on the quality of the education
received by its graduates as far as an acquaintance with the latest legal
developments is concerned. There is no hint that Gorbachev devoted himself
seriously to the study of the great works in the area of law. Evening studies
at the Agricultural Institute in Stavropol, from which he graduated, probably
did not broaden his intellectual range. The career upon which Gorbachev
embarked in Stavropol demanded the utmost effort and cunning: he first had to
climb to the top of the local hierarchy, and subsequently he had to struggle in
the upper echelons of the party apparatus. At the same time, Gorbachev is not totally
indifferent to cultural concerns: he genuinely loves theatre, and apparently
used to write poetry.
Gorbachev's example is typical of Soviet
leaders: they are highly qualified in achieving, expanding and maintaining
their power, but their overall culture is rather primitive compare to the
demands of managing a complex country with an autocratic regime. In other
words, Soviet leaders are experts at political intrigue but are poor statesman.
I know many of
Gorbachev's advisers personally. Most of them are gifted people deeply
concerned with the situation in the country. They are all over fifty years old,
they all received socioeconomic education at Soviet colleges which taught at
roughly the level of the beginning of nineteenth century. The governing doctrine
of Marxism-the pinnacle of all these sciences-has made the graduates of Soviet
institutions ignorant of the great achievements of world thought in philosophy,
sociology, economics, etc. In subsequent years these people, for various
reasons, also lacked an opportunity to seriously devote themselves to the study
of the latest developments in their own fields. Naturally, being actively
involved in the reforms, they are bound to learn. But how many years and how
many mistakes will it take before they reach the level of modern science if
they have to rediscover the paradigms that have been discovered in their
respective fields over the last 150 years?
Unfortunately,
as far as getting acquainted with the latest developments of world thought, the
situation of the younger generation studying socioeconomic sciences and
humanities,, has not changed significantly. It will take some time before the
criticism of Marxism, which has just started in the Soviet Union, will become
constructive, in the sense that students will study world thought after Marx.
Individual Soviet scholars in socioeconomic sciences who are on a par with
world standards are still very far from Gorbachev or his advisers; moreover,
they are prevented from active involvement in teaching the new generation of
teachers and students.
But let us go
back to the politics of Gorbachev. Assuming that Gorbachev is pursuing a
centrist policy with the intention of preserving an autocratic imperial regime
using flexible methods, we can give one possible interpretation of Gorbachev's
position in relation to various political movements in the country. Gorbachev
does not curtail the development even of opposing trends: in case liberal
reforms fail he can always saddle a different horse. He is moderate in his support
of liberal, conservative and even reactionary circles. This became evident at
the June 1989 Congress of the People's Deputies. He gave the first word to
Andrey Sakharov, but soon interrupted his rather critical speech, apologizing
for not having warned him of a five-minute limit. At the final meeting when
Sakharov asked to speak, Gorbachev addressed the audience about granting
Sakharov a word. The response was an ear shattering "No!". Still,
Gorbachev allowed Sakharov to speak, but when the time limit expired (I believe
it was doubled) he turned off the microphone.
At one point,
Gorbachev stood up to applaud a veteran of the Afghanistan war who attacked
Sakharov for condemning this war and exposing its cruel side. Taking into
account the strong patriotic zeal of the county, which justifies Soviet
militarism in the eyes of the great majority of Russian people and oftentimes
even of the intelligentsia, this demonstrative act cast a shadow upon
Sakharov's reputation.
Gorbachev's
game is complex perhaps because Gorbachev's entourage includes many leaders who
believe in the more rigid methods of preserving an autocratic imperial state.
These people extend their utmost support to those who adhere to these views. On
the one hand these hard-liners impede a more methodical implementation of the
more liberal aspects of Gorbachev's policy; on the other hand, this group gives
him an opportunity to support the circles opposing the hard-liners. Gorbachev
needs those who oppose the hard-liners in case he decides to demolish these
leaders of the hard-liners. One could well maintain that Gorbachev would like
to remove some of these men, if only because many of them did not come to power
on his accord. At the same time, as long as they are around and hard to
replace, and as long as they are under
control and make no attempt to dethrone
Gorbachev, he can be more tolerant and try to use the results of their work for
his own benefit. If necessary (as with the leaders of the liberal front)
Gorbachev may try to discredit them just to weaken their popularity and to
prevent them from usurping power. Interesting in this respect is the conduct of
N. Ivanov, a prosecutor who was one of
the instigators of the investigation into corruption in the highest echelons of
the government. Ivanov was elected a Peoples' Deputy from Leningrad. In his
election campaign, he spoke on Leningrad television naming the people linked to
the corruption. Among those mentioned were not only the recently expelled
member of Politburo Mikhail Solomentsev, but also Egor Ligachev. Ligachev has
been widely regarded as one of the leaders of the right wing, the man who
inspired the Russian national-socialist manifesto, although the manifesto first
appeared as a letter, by Nina Andreeva, published in the newspaper Sovietskaia
Rossiia on 13 March 1988.
At this point
I would like to advance some arguments in support of my thesis that Gorbachev
is trying to maintain an autocratic empire, using a flexible approach.
Testifying to Gorbachev's desire to preserve autocracy is his unshakable intent
to acquire dual power both as president of the country and as first secretary
of the Communist party. Academician Sakharov, as well as a number of delegates
to the 1988 party conference headed by Academicians Leonid Abalkin and Roald Sagdeev,
spoke against this merger. Their arguments were quite simple: concentration of
power in the hands of one person is fraught with grave dangers, especially if
at some future point the power should fall into the hands of a person "unworthy of of trust."
Nevertheless, at the party conference Gorbachev's move was adopted by a
majority of several thousand votes (only 208 delegates voted against
Gorbachev's suggestion) and it is now being carried out in practice. At the May
1989 Congress of People's Deputies it was proposed to have several candidates
for the post of president, of having Gorbachev report to the congress on the
previous period, to separate the power of the president and the first secretary
of the party, etc. All these proposals were rejected and Gorbachev managed
through political intrigue to get elected to the post of president and still
maintain his position as first secretary.
The empire is
by no means being disbanded by Gorbachev. The rather cruel suppression of
demonstrations in Georgia and Moldavia, really organized under the banner of
political independence, are a testimony to this. It would not be too farfetched
to suppose that greater flexibility will be shown toward the Baltic states.
Perhaps they will be allowed to leave the happy Soviet family. . . to hold the
same status as other Eastern European countries. The reason for this
exceptional move may be the still-fresh memory of the coercive annexation of
these republics by Russia after the signing of the pact between Stalin and Hitler
in 1939. These events were accompanied by many human losses, first and foremost
as a result of the massive exile of the native population of these regions to
Siberia. As far as the Eastern European countries are concerned, the most
rebellious ones, such as Hungary and Poland, may be granted the status of
Finland. To sum up, my hypothesis that Gorbachev is not altering the Russian
tradition seems to hold: he is sticking to the invariants of Russian history
though employing more flexible methods in doing so. Once again, in speaking of
Gorbachev's policies with respect to Russian traditions, I do not mean his intentions but the actual institutions
he is creating. Here I want to remark that as long as autocracy cannot be
replaced, I am in favor of this flexible approach to maintaining the
regime,rather than the more rigid methods. Moreover, since flexible ways of
preserving an autocratic empire can in principle lead to a democracy, judging
this kind of policy becomes ever- more difficult. At the same time, one should
not confuse democratization with a more flexible preservation of autocracy so
as to be better prepared to employ such methods. And one should not be
dumbstruck when the leader resorts to means foreign to the spirit of democracy.
Of course, in reality this distinction is hard to spot, for on the surface
democratization and flexibility in the preservation of autocracy seem rather
similar. The question of whether what is taking place in the Soviet Union is
democratization or flexibility in upholding an autocratic empire is very
relevant in solving some practical problems of Russian development.
For instance,
a share of liberally minded intelligentsia believes that, since the U.S.S.R. is
really undergoing a process of democratization, the transformation to regional
autonomy may be conducted within the framework of a democratic regime, that is,
without the violent demonstrations and ensuing bloodshed that, the radical
nationalistic circles are advocating. If the Soviet Union is indeed undergoing
the process of democratization, then these liberal circles of intelligentsia
would be correct. But if the Soviet Union is really experiencing an autocratic
imperial regime, even though supported by flexible methods, then perhaps other
groups advocating more radical solutions are right: under the pressure from the
populace the government may make considerable concessions. Of course,
radicalism may lead to excesses having negative repercussions: very strong
jolts in the republics may cause those in power to take a sharp turn and revert
back to rigid policies of ruling the country.
The Liberalization of Russia: The
Paradox of Glasnost!
From a general
standpoint, the reanimation of the stagnant Soviet system that is being carried
out in the Soviet Union through the vehicle of glasnost, that is, by activating
the citizenry under conditions of greater freedom, is worthy of the respect of
all liberal-minded persons.
To be certain,
all of these liberal changes are not taking place uniformly. Even as this book is being written, there
are already equally apparent signs of opposite tendencies. I have in mind statements made by a number
of Soviet officials thought to be sympathetic to the liberal cause, especially Politburo member Alexander Iakovlev,
demanding that the screws be tightened.
However, for
the purposes of this book I am going to proceed from the extreme case, that is,
on the assumption that the campaign of glasnost is developing full swing in
the U.S.S.R. and that the appearance of
nonliberal articles is also a manifestation of the growing multiplicity of
ideas.
Furthermore,
and once again proceeding from the extreme case, I will tie the development of
glasnost at the present time with the name of Gorbachev. Meanwhile, we must remember that Gorbachev
began his activity using the extremely traditional Soviet methods of
stimulating economic growth, in particular, attempts to resurrect the Stakhanov
movement.
In May of
1985, at Michigan State University, Professor Vladimir E. Shliapentokh
organized a one-day seminar devoted to the fiftieth anniversary of the
Stakhanov movement in the U.S.S.R. One
of the goals of that seminar, according to Shliapentokh, was the verification
of the parameters according to which one could judge the intentions of the
then-new Soviet leader Gorbachev. Based
on how preparations for the celebration itself were conducted, it would be
possible to try to judge in what direction Gorbachev intends to develop Soviet
society in the near future. I valued
Shliapentokh's idea very highly and participated in the work of the seminar
with great interest.
It is
well-known that the Stakhanov movement embodies the demagogically most
primitive methods of economic development.
It is also well-known that Gorbachev celebrated this anniversary with
great fanfare and took a personal part in the ceremonies. It is likewise known that soon afterwards,
Gorbachev started implementing quite a different policy of reviving the
economy.
By saying this
I in no way mean to debunk the value of attempts to forecast Gorbachev's
actions. On the contrary, from this
experience one can draw a very far-reaching conclusion: we are now dealing with a very flexible
Soviet leader and forecasts of his likely activity require the development of
very sophisticated methods.
It is still
far from clear in just what direction Gorbachev will evolve. I cannot caution the reader enough to be
extremely careful in evaluating Gorbachev's activities, since he is still in
the developmental stage as a leader. Just as he evolved rapidly from an
ordinary Soviet apparatchik to a revolutionizing figure with liberal leanings,
we cannot exclude the possibility that he might well take steps in a different
direction should he find himself faced with a rapidly changing set of
circumstances.
The method
that I am suggesting here for examining the role of glasnost in the modern
period of Russia's development is
substantially different from the approach that is currently widely accepted. For all intents and purposes glasnost, in
and of itself, is seen as a positive development in the sense that most feel
that the more it develops and the faster it develops, the better. Opinions tend to differ only with respect to
such questions as how sincere glasnost
is and to what extent it is sufficient to transform a stagnant Soviet
society.
In this
connection, an opinion survey conducted in 1987 by the magazine The Nation
among a number of renowned Soviet emigres on their attitudes towards glasnost
is of great interest.[29] Lev Kopelev, Iurij Orlov, Valery
Chalidze, and Alexander Yanov all hold the view that the policy of glasnost
that is currently being implemented in the U.S.S.R. not only is not fiction,
but it is a significant phenomenon that can easily be seen as the beginning of
a democratization of the Soviet Union.
Vladimir Voinovich and Zhores Medvedev hold very similar views, but they
are essentially more critical in their evaluations of the results that have
already been achieved under glasnost.
However, all these respondents felt that, in order to truly achieve a
democratization of Soviet society, further meaningful steps would have to be
taken. In Orlov's opinion the
significance of these steps could be so great, and therefore the unwillingness
of the Soviet leaders to carry out these measures could be so strong, that he
feels that it will not be possible to achieve a true democratization of the
U.S.S.R. for at least another decade. Vladimir Maksimov expressed a more
extreme view. While he doesn't deny
that restrictions on basic freedoms have been loosened recently in the
U.S.S.R., he doesn't really see this as a significant development since, in his
view, until the time when a legal opposition to the existing regime can be
created, it is impossible to speak of any significant changes in the Soviet
system.
My views of
glasnost are quite the opposite: that is to say, the more widely and rapidly
the policy of glasnost is implemented, the greater will be the threat it poses
not only to the U.S.S.R., but to other countries as well.[30] My views are basically in line with the
considerations advanced in chapter 2 regarding the incompatibility of pluralism
and democracy given, especially at a time of crisis, the populace's low level of culture. Needless to say, I am not
against increased glasnost insofar as it is confined to hard-hitting
intellectual journalism, free-wheeling scholarly discussions, and the like. I
only think it unwise to bring glasnost down to the grass roots level, and
particularly allow mass organizations and demonstrations or popular publications
and statements (especially on TV) designed to stir up ethnic resentments and
similar antagonisms.
Bearing this
in mind, in the present work I
primarily wish to examine the problem of how the mobilization of the Soviet
population, accompanied by a relaxation of the regime's strictness, might well
lead to the opposite result, that is, to the creation of an even stricter
regime, marked by unabashed militarism and chauvinism. Whether Gorbachev himself would become the
leader of such a regime (in a more toned-down
form[31]) or whether he would be replaced by
someone else, is difficult for me to say.
So my
hypothesis is that glasnost introduced in the U.S.S.R. under Gorbachev can lead
to a triumph of nationalistic policy. Based on the general considerations regarding
the conflict between pluralism and democracy, I want to state some
considerations supporting my statement.
The process of
the activation of the Soviet people taking place under Gorbachev's leadership
is seen by many Soviet specialists primarily in the context of a binary
approach, that is an analysis finds, on
the one hand, a liberal Gorbachev who is trying to mobilize the Soviet citizenry,
and, on the other hand, conservatives who want to retain the calm, secure life
to which they grew accustomed during the last twenty years of Brezhnev's rule.
Meanwhile, if
we go from a binary to a tripartite approach, our task is made significantly
more complicated (just as is the case in mechanics when we switch from a task
involving two bodies to a task involving three). If we adopt this approach, we can clearly see one more broad and
important group-reactionaries. Unlike
conservatives, who by definition strive to preserve the status quo,
reactionaries seek changes. In this
respect, reactionaries and liberals are similar. They are distinguished by the changes that they advocate:
liberals push for changes toward democratization, whereas reactionaries seek to
establish authoritarian and even dictatorial, chauvinistic regimes.[32]
The sort of
three-pronged approach acquires particular significance if we take into account
the fact that the transformations being ushered in by Gorbachev are taking
place in a period in which the world's last big empire, with a tradition of
expansionism and nationalism, including its extreme chauvinistic forms, is
suffering stagnation. It follows, then, that the activation that is taking
place could be used not only by liberal circles, but by reactionary ones as
well. Moreover, the paradoxical nature
of the events taking place under Gorbachev consists in the fact that the
reactionaries can exploit the opportunities created by restructuring to an
even greater degree than can the liberals, since the reactionaries have on
their side the sympathies of the masses of the Russian population, which
traditionally has supported nationalistic ideas. These reactionaries, being fanatics, can act more decisively and
can do a great deal more to promote a rebirth of the Russian people's faith in
their future. They can in many ways
further the steamlining of the economic mechanism, first and foremost through
its decentralization and liberation from the tutelage of the party. Additionally, in aspirations as a world
power, they can even more decisively set Russia on a course of expansion,
believing in its messianic role as the savior of the world.
In other
words, I am advancing the following hypothesis: under the conditions of a stagnating empire with militaristic and
nationalistic traditions, the strengthening of glasnost, manifested in the
activation of the populace, could lead not to a liberalization of the country,
but rather, in the extreme case, to the establishment of a hard-line
authoritarian, militaristic, and nationalistic regime headed by fanatical
leaders.
Notes and References
4
Expansion of the Soviet
Empire
A Semi-Forbidden Topic
In it's current position, the Russian empire occupies a
huge territory -- more that one-seventh of the earth's dry land -- with a
population of 290 million people, and a gigantic military potential. This empire
consists of several circles. The first circle is the mother country proper, in
which the overwhelming majority of the population is Russian. The second circle
includes the territories where other nationalities live, for whom the territory
is historically their native land and who are entirely subordinate to the
Russian dictate. The second circle includes the Soviet republics and autonomous
republics. The third circle includes countries that are formally considered to
be sovereign nations but that are actually subordinate to Russia, since the
latter's troops may suppress any attempt they make to extract themselves from
the empire. It is true that the Russian dictate does have obvious limitations
here (the absence of an official representative of Russian nationality in the
leadership of such a country, the fact that it is not mandatory for the
populations to use the Russian language, and the like). The third circle is
comprised primarily of Eastern European countries. Finally, the fourth circle
includes countries that, realistically observing their neutrality, are located
in the sphere of strong Russian influence, and largely depend on it in military
matters (for the delivery of weapons and the training of military staff). This
group of countries primarily includes, at various times, various developing
nations of the Third World such as Egypt, Indonesia, Syria, Somalia, and
others.
The Russian empire has many features in common with other
empires, but it also has some traits that have had a significant influence on
its development. Specifically, there are traits in connection with the colonial
empire (the first, second, and third circles) that make the maintenance of the
Russian empire difficult: the inclusion in the empire's orbit of territories
that are more economically advanced than the mother country (the inclusion, for
example, of the Baltic region,
Czechoslovakia, East Germany, or Hungary); the close proximity of the main mass
of territory making up the empire either to the mother country or the second
circle; the development mechanisms of the mother country itself, which are
insufficiently efficient compared with
the mechanisms of more-developed countries subordinate to Russia, and which
therefore lead to the formation of development programs for the client
countries which sometimes prove disastrous for these countries: it was not a
coincidence for Russia (nor for the English or the French empires) that
Europe's role as the gendarme was strengthened.
The democratization of the U.S.S.R. rests on the problem of
preserving the empire, as its inhabitants are longing for self-determination.
Resolving the issue of freedom in the U.S.S.R. ultimately means allowing its
peoples to demand secession from the body of the empire, as well as permitting
countries belonging to the third circle to pull out.
The problems currently tearing Russia apart are connected
with the deep-seated conflict between the fortification of the last great
empire in the world and the stagnation of its society and economy. The crisis
situation in which the country finds itself is to a large degree the result of
the accepted conception of development, which was founded on the idea of
maintaining and expanding the empire. In the list of the Soviet leaders'
priorities, second place, after the preservation of their own personal power,
has been and presently is assumed by the aim of strengthening the might of the
empire. This is the dominant aim, and the economy is subordinate to the goals
of the empire.
Such a successful
combinative game conceals within itself the threat of a Pyrrhic victory, the
unavoidable companion of a combinative game if one disregards the positional
strength of the system. It seems to me
that this "victory" began at the end of the 1970s; the suspension of growth in heavy industry
along with the downgrading of agriculture and light industry, the failures in
the military sphere (for example, the complete discrediting of Soviet weaponry
during the Lebanese war, the unsuccessful war in Afghanistan, the landing of
the West German plane on Red Square), and the inability to withstand seriously
Reagan's call for Star Wars seem to me to be the results of the profound
exhaustion of the nation's potential. In other words, the current decline in
economic activity and military might are not results of present fluctuations,
but rather the results of a disfiguring war economy and its accompanying
methods of government.
A huge gap has arisen between the needs of the empire, the
interests of its inhabitants, and the available natural and human resources, as
well as the capital on hand. The country's production has turned out to be
insufficient to maintain its status as a superpower able to satisfy the modern
military requirements vital to expanding the empire, and to increase its
population's standard of living.
In order to overcome these difficulties, it is not enough
to improve the economic mechanism. It is of primary importance for the nation
to relieve itself of the burden of maintaining the empire.
The force of these
conflicts between imperial aspirations and economic capacity to fulfill them
had reached such a level that Gorbachev announced his policy of glasnost and
perestroika in order to bring ambition and ammunition into an equilibrium. In
the course of glasnost, extremely significant aspects of life in Soviet
society, which were earlier considered taboo, were immediately brought to
light. Amongst these changes, those that directly concern the empire are, as
usual, closed issues. This is not to say that the fate of the empire is not being
discussed. It is being discussed very seriously, but not out loud.
With the announcement of glasnost, issues pertaining to the
empire began to be discussed in an indirect manner. Indirect repercussions of the thorny discussion concerning the
dilemma of the Soviet empire penetrate the general press under the guise of
topics that seem isolated from this problem. Popular among these topics is the
study of local languages and of the Russian language in the various republics.
In order to get a perspective on this issue, it will suffice to compare the
article "The Slavs: Language and History" published in Pravda
on 28 March 1987 ( by Oleg N.
Trubachev, a correspondent member of the U.S.S.R.'s Academy of Science) with
the works of writers from the non-Russian republics at the April 1987 Plenum of
the Soviet Writers' Union, as published in Literary Gazette on 6 May
1987.
In Trubachev's article, it is plainly stated that the
Russian language is the dominant language and that local languages should be
subordinate to it.
During the Writers' Union plenum, writers representing the
Ukraine and Byelorussia mainly addressed the necessity of organizing
instruction in the local languages at the school level, since this area of
education is appallingly lacking. Boris Olejnik (from the Ukraine) candidly
stated that "in several of our regional centers the number of Ukranian
schools is approaching zero."
These writers have correctly observed that without the
population's knowledge of the local language, the development of national
literature in the republics will suffer. It is interesting to note that the
writers' presentation was supported by a semi-official, the secretary of the
Writers' Union of the Russian Republic, Sergey Mikhalkov.
This does not mean that among writers representing the
national republics there were none who supported the russification of the
republics. Thus, a representative of Uzbekistan, Ulmas Umarbekov, complained
that in the republic "in the recent past, Uzbek writers writing in Russian
were subject to discrimination." However, this was the only pro-Russian
demonstration by a non-Russian.
When comparing the allowances made in the name of glasnost
concerning many economic and social issues and the lack of allowance concerning
others, one gets the impression that the current Soviet administration is
prepared for rather decisive action directed towards ideological changes at the
socioeconomic level, but that it is not prepared for any sort of significant
changes regarding the eradication of the empire. This chapter deals with one
such change related to the eradication of the empire.
As glasnost gathers momentum, the empire has become more
and more a subject of discussion. The greatest revelation in this respect has
been the critical assessment of Soviet foreign policy when it was acknowledged
to be hegemonic and based on offensive military strategy.
Of greatest significance in the discussion of internal
imperial policy has been the medias publicizing of the many regional conflicts
flaring up in the U.S.S.R.: conflicts between Armenians and Azerbaijanians over
Nagorno-Karabakh, between Abkhazians and Georgians, between Uzbeks and
Meskhets, the direct claims for independence on the part of the Baltic
republics, etc.
Seven Hundred Years of
Imperial Tradition
What then is the principal reason keeping Soviet leaders
from parting with the empire? Actually, a very simple answer comes to mind: the
fear of losing the prestige enjoyed by leaders of a world superpower. Yes, such
an answer may actually prove sufficient to explain the U.S.S.R.'s imperial
policies. However, it still appears that there are a number of important
factors that aggravate the situation, and that would still interfere with
Soviet leaders' rejecting the empire, even if for some reason they discovered
that their prestige in world history would increase if they eradicated the
empire. One of these key factors is the nation's tradition.[33]
If we look at Russia's history over the past seven hundred
years, beginning with Ivan Kalita and continuing up to today's administration,
we observe that the empire has continually expanded and strengthened. During
this period, not even one other imperial nation was able to maintain its power;
but Russia managed to do so.
Along these lines, it is fascinating to trace the
characteristics of the more significant Russian leaders all the way up to
Stalin as depicted in The Encyclopedic Dictionary. Since it was
published in the U.S.S.R. from 1953--55, it largely reflects Stalin's extremely
aggressive postwar expansionist policy (I will go into detail about this policy
later).
• Ivan I
Danilovich Kalita (?--1340): "Great Prince of Muscovy." "One of
the first to unify the Russian land under power of Moscow principality."
• Ivan III
Vasilevich (1440--1505): "Great King of Muscovy and of all Russia,"
"great political figure." "Chiefly accomplished the unification
of scattered Russian provinces around Moscow into a single Russian
government." "Conducted successful wars with Livonia, Poland, Lithuania.
Significantly strengthened and expanded the Russian nation."
• Ivan IV
Vasilevich Grozny (1530--84): "Great Prince of all Russia,"
"leading political figure." "During the reign of Ivan IV the
centralization of Russia's rule was strengthened into a single autocratic
power." "Conquered the Kazan (1552) and Astrakhan (1556) tatar
Khanates, seized the entire Volga region and subjugated the Nogai hordes to
Moscow along with the Siberian kingdom, annexed numerous peoples in the
northern Caucasus region to the Russian nation."
• Peter I
Alexeyevich (1672--1725): "Emperor," "Great political figure,
general, naval commander and diplomat." "In the sphere of foreign
policy P. I waged a consistent battle for access to the sea, as this was a
vital condition for the further expansion of the country." "The
Turkish War . . . and in particular the Northern War . . . against the Swedes
in support of the nation, monumental victories were celebrated all around, at
sea and on land. . . . Russia controlled the extremely crucial Baltic seacoast."
• Katherine II
Alexeevna (1729--1796): "Russian Empress." "Strengthened the
system of serfdom in every way possible." "Under K. II successful
wars were waged against Turkey . . . and Sweden; the division of Poland took
place, . . . according to which the Ukranian and Byelorussian lands passed to
Russia. The Crimea was annexed to the Russian empire, . . . joined under the
auspices of Georgia."
• Alexander I
(1777--1825): "Russian Emperor." Waged war with France, Sweden,
Turkey and Persia." "Under A. I Georgia, Finland, and Bessarabia were
annexed to Russia."
• Alexander II
(1818--1881): "Russian Emperor." "Confirmed advocate of
serfdom," was forced to conduct the emancipation of the serfs in 1861.
"During the reign of A. II, the territory of the Russian empire increased
due to the annexation of numerous territories of Central Asia and the Far
East."
• Stalin (21
December 1879 -- 5 March 1953):
"Loyal pupil and brother-in-arms of V. I. Lenin, great successor of his
immortal deeds, leader and teacher of the Communist party of the Soviet Union,
the Soviet people and the workers of all countries." "In the postwar
period fundamental changes took place in international relations. A number of
European and Asian countries turned away from capitalism and fortified the
foundation of popular democracy as the people took power into their own hands.
The end of 1949 ushered in an event of worldwide historical significance -- the
formation of the People's Republic of China. Relations between the Soviet Union
and other countries with a people's democracy were founded on the basis of fair
treaties, relations of friendship, mutual assistance and cooperation."
I will discuss the characteristics of the political leaders
that succeeded Stalin and their policies of expansion later.
The expansion of the Russian empire was not consistent, of
course, in the sense that situations did arise when Russia was obligated to
sacrifice certain territories. These sacrifices were as a rule conditioned by
Russia's defeat in various wars (for instance, the loss of a part of Bessarabia
after defeat in the Crimean War), the result of political and economic
difficulties, and the expediency of selling certain territories (as was the
case with Alaska under Alexander II). Usually these sacrifices were only
temporary, that is, these territories were quickly returned, often with
interest. Thus, Bessarabia was returned to the same Alexander II who gave it
away after defeat in the Crimean War. A number of the empire's Western
territories, given away by Lenin and quickly regained under Stalin, deserve
special attention here.
In this connection, the role of Lenin in the development of
the Russian empire and the position of the empire under Lenin after the October
Revolution should be observed carefully. The statements that I make below are
purely subjective and speculative. My primary goal here is to encourage the
reader to reflect on several peculiarities of this period.
It is interesting to recall who, in the period before the
October Revolution, made the loudest noise about Russia being a prison for the
people and who declared that these people must be freed from Russia. It was the
same communists, chief among them Lenin, who after the successful Revolution
fought harder than anyone for the preservation of imperial unity, now referring
to it as socialist cooperation, as only a unified population could more quickly
attain that shining future. Why do separate peoples who already have ties with
Russia, they reasoned, need to secede from this most progressive system and
establish their own governments when, sooner or later, in accordance with
Marxist doctrine, they willl all be living under communism?[34]
Wasn't it because of this endeavor to maintain the empire
that the Bolshevik leaders, mainly Trotsky and Lenin, wound up using the
tsarist military staff in order to establish the Red Army and win the Civil
War? And isn't it these same circumstances that explain the prevailing role
tsarist officers played in the development of the Red Army in later years? And
wasn't it chiefly these same military men that Stalin liquidated during the
great purges of 1937? And wasn't it primarily the survivors among these
military men that Stalin freed from the labor camps when the war with Germany
began? Wasn't it, then, former tsarist officers who played a decisive role in
the Soviet Army's victory over Hitler? Wasn't it these former tsarist generals
and other officers who refused to cooperate with Hitler during the war with
Russia?
Which
of the formerly imperial territories that Lenin gave back after the Revolution
again became independent nations (albeit for a short period of time)? The
answer: only a few Western territories: Finland, Lithuania, Latvia, Estonia,
and Poland. The case of Poland is especially relevant here, because Poland had
a long common border with Germany, which at that time experienced a strong
revolutionary movement.[35]
It
seems ironic that Trotsky, the most outspoken and consistent proponent of the
idea of permanent revolution, was opposed to the attack on Warsaw in 1920,
averring the inadequacy of Russia's resources, both material and human.
According to Trotsky, the chief supporter of that campaign was Lenin. It seems
strange that Lenin, who usually followed Trotsky's advice, especially in
military matters, took the opposite stance. But let us assume that in that
period Lenin was even more radically minded than Trotsky, and wanted to join
forces with German revolutionaries by achieving a quick victory over Poland.
The
Warsaw episode was a failure for the Red Army. "The outcome of the Polish
war," wrote Trotsky, "proved to be a decisive factor in the
subsequent development of Russia. The Riga Peace Treaty with Poland cut us off
from Germany, and strongly impacted on the fate of Soviets in Germany."
If
Lenin were genuinely interested in preserving Poland as part of his new empire,
he would have shown his renowned willpower to commit everything to the defeat
of Pilsudski, and his customary
intolerance, to severely punish any underling who would dare undermine his
plans. Even if the defeat were to be acknowledged and a peace treaty signed, it
could have been done in such a way as to quickly reposition the Red Army forces
and try to subdue Poland again.
In
the event, something altogether different happened.
Retreat
from Poland, the pullout of the Red Army from Poland, is usually explained by
the following argument, a rather strange one for the communists: "the army
was cut off from its reserves."
We
know that there was another equally weighty cause of the failure in Poland: the
South Western Army, in whose command Stalin, as a Central Committee
representative, played a leading role, ignored the repeated orders of the High
Command and failed to cover the flank of the Tukhachevsky's army advancing to
Warsaw. Instead, Stalin, pursuing his
own ambitious goals, demanded that the South Western Army move into Lvov. If
Lenin had been determined to bring the Red Army closer to Germany, he would
have raked Stalin over the coals for insubordination. In fact, he did nothing
of the sort. As I recall from my readings on the subject, Lenin just made some
sardonic remark, and let the whole issue go at that. Possibly, among Lenin's
disciples, Stalin understood him better than all the rest, including Trotsky.
But if we assume that Lenin was not really interested in
supporting the revolutionary movements in Western Europe in general and in
Germany in particular, the whole Polish episode would look very different
indeed.
The suspicion arises that perhaps it was convenient for
Lenin to give up these territories in order to create a buffer zone between the
U.S.S.R. and the developed Western-European nations that border on them. This
suspicion actually has some basis if we assume that Lenin, having tasted the
fruits of what it was like to be the champion of the world's proletariat,
(having officially become the leader of the Third Communist International in
1919), strove more than anything to retain his own hegemony as the leader of
the world's proletariat. Lenin, then, should have been very wary of the
revolutionary situation in the developed Western-European nations. He expressed
this fear candidly enough in his book Left-Wing Communism: An Infant
Disorder, written in April and May of 1920. Lenin had very serious reasons
for his fears. The people of Western Europe had experienced the destruction
brought about by the monstrous First World War. And it was precisely the
communists, not the socialists, who had denounced this war. Also, the
victorious Revolution in Russia declared, as one of its first slogans,
"PEACE." Victorious revolutions in these countries might push
backward, unindustrialized Russia off to the side, in accordance with Marxist theory. Having established a buffer
zone, Lenin temporarily relieved himself of the burden of being obligated to
assist the proletariat of Western-European countries in his efforts to
establish socialist political systems. It is a different matter that in the
1930s, the buffer zone was transformed into a "sanitary cordon" for
the purpose of discouraging the penetration of the communist bacillus from
Russia to Western Europe.
As we know, Stalin not only retrieved territories given
back by Lenin (with the exception of a large portion of Finland, which was
exchanged for the Finlandization of the country), but he increased them.
The speculative observations that I have made regarding
Lenin's relationship to the empire allows one to understand more clearly the
conflict that arose among the Soviet communists soon after the Revolution about
the future of the Russian empire. The rift
became particularly noticeable immediately after Lenin's death, and it
even seems that Lenin himself could not arrive at a final solution, or more
specifically, could not arrive at an open solution to this issue. Disagreement
divided into the following two conceptions: The first says that humanity's
salvation will come through Russia, that is, through Russia's guidance of the
international communist movement. Everything that is beneficial for Russia is
beneficial for for the worldwide communist movement. This conception is called
"the victory of socialism in one country." This view was held by
Stalin, Bukharin, Rykov, and others. The second conception holds that world
communism will come through international revolution, and if it is necessary that
Russia burn in the flames of worldwide revolution in the name of victory, then
let it be so. Trotsky, Zinoviev, and Kamenev were adherents of this philosophy.
The first conception, which completely coincided with
Russia's historical tradition, prevailed. For many years it predetermined the
development of the Russian empire under the Bolsheviks. Russian patriots, the evrazijtsy
in particular, judged correctly that the Bolsheviks' communist slogans were not
as important as was maintaining and expanding the empire. In actuality, it
turns out that they were right in the sense that in the end, particularly
beginning with Brezhnev's administration, the communist ideology lost its
importance.
Thus, throughout Russia's entire history, leaders of
various caliber (the great ones, the outstanding ones, the unsurpassable ones,
and even the Teacher of the Peoples and Proletarians of All the World)
invariably fortified the empire, although the leaders' motives have very
seriously changed. It is precisely for an understanding of Gorbachev's policies
that it is important for us to understand the invariance of the
tradition of strengthening the empire, rather than become too caught up in the
motives that guided previous leaders.
Declared motives
for the maintenance and expansion of the empire have been modified by
everything from egoistical Russian interests (such as Russia's need to find
access to the ocean, particularly ports that are navigable in winter), to the
fulfillment of well-meaning missions to assist brother Slavs, to the overall
salvation of humanity.
I do not mean to
imply that the fortification of the Russian empire always took place with the
same degree of intensity and was constantly accompanied by a strict regimen
always leading to tyranny. During Russia's history, and even in recent Soviet
history, there have been various periods that differed significantly in the
rate of imperial expansion and in the corresponding political atmosphere of the
country.
Stalinist and Post-Stalinist Imperial Policy
I will compare two periods in the history of the Russian
empire under Soviet power in order to demonstrate which significant
distinctions in the country's development fall under the category of
maintaining the empire and its authoritarian system (not to be confused with a
dictatorial or a tyrannical regime)
It is necessary to note that early Russian expansionist
policy did not aspire to world domination: Russia aspired to be accepted as a
full member in the circle of European nations. Of the many ideologies Russia
had an ideology that aspired to Russia's domination over the whole world,
believing that Orthodoxy can also be read as "the Slavs are
correct" [In Russian the word orthodoxy is made up of the words pravo, 'correct' and slavia,
'believing'; slavia is also the root of the word Slav.--Trans.],
that Russia, the only major bearer of Orthodoxy, must rescue the Western world
from spiritual desolation, and that "Russia is the third Rome and a fourth
one there will not be." However, it was not entirely the ideology that set
the tone of Russian imperial policy.
The situation changed markedly after the victory of the
October Revolution in 1917. The triumph of the Revolution, whose ideology was
internationalist and required expansion over the entire world, was a refracted
one that, as I have noted above in discussing Leninist-Stalinist ambitions,
assigned primary importance in Soviet foreign policy to the global interests of
world domination.
I believe that Lenin belonged to the class of leaders who
would give their last breath to support the construction of world communism.
However, as far as Stalin is concerned, such a statement is more debatable.
Having become the leader of a vast empire that had emerged relatively rapidly
-- in less than twenty years, such was its power and capability for expansion
-- Stalin may have had the desire to become emperor of the world simply in
order to expand his own power. Whether or not this was the case, the empire
became powerful enough so that toward the middle of the 1950s, Stalin could
seriously begin to hope for a new world war with the expectation of bringing
closer his secret dream of becoming a world dictator. (It was apparently not a
coincidence that Stalin was not enamored with Charlie Chaplin after seeing his
film Dictator which ridicules a man's strivings to become ruler of the
world.)
Such a statement is, of course, very controversial; however, it is well-founded. Mainly, in the
beginning of the 1950s, Stalin had a huge army experienced in modern methods of
warfare, and an industrial complex that could supply this army with modern
weapons. The army's size was significantly larger that the armies of the United
States and England; France, Germany, and Italy were defeated countries and
their military potential was low. Also, the United States' main strength was in
its possession of atomic weapons and the means for delivering them over large
distances. Stalin had the bomb by 1948 and in August of 1953, (literally a few
months after his death), the hydrogen bomb was successfully tested in the
U.S.S.R. True, Stalin did not have the means to deliver this lethal weapon to
the den of his chief enemy, the United States. But he did have hostages: if it
became necessary, he could use this weapon on the United States' allies in
Western Europe. The main method was rockets: the first Soviet satellite was
successfully launched 4 October 1957. Thus, Stalin had the opportunity to use
his advantage in conventional weapons to paralyze the use of atomic weapons. If
we also consider the strength of the communist parties in Western Europe,
China's triumph, the weakness of Japan and India, and the complete helplessness
of the countries on the African continent, then Stalin had a good chance of
expanding the empire at least to three continents: Europe, Asia, and Africa;
and maybe even very soon, thanks to the power he had achieved, to the Americas.
In this connection, it is interesting to take a look at
ideology during the last years of Stalin's reign. In my opinion, it completely
corresponds with the assumptions about preparations for a third world war whose
purpose was to turn Russia into a worldwide empire, its dominion over the whole
world led by Stalin. In this respect, more candid comments were made by G. M.
Malenkov, the secretary of the Central Committee, who presented the Current
Report of the Central Committee at the 19th Party Congress in October 1952:
It is impossible not to consider the facts of the past.
These facts demonstrate that as a result of the First World War, Russia fell
away from a system of capitalism, and as a result of the Second World War
numerous countries in Europe and Asia also turned from capitalism. There is
every reason to believe that a third world war would bring about the collapse
of the global capitalist system [prolonged applause].
These are, so to speak, the perspectives and consequences
of a war should it be imposed on the people by the war-mongers, the aggressors.
Stalin also participated in this session with a short but
expressive speech, in which he appealed to Western communists to seize power in
their countries:
The banner of bourgeoisie-democratic freedom has been
thrown overboard. I think that it has fallen to you, the representatives of
communist and democratic parties, to take up this banner and carry it forward
if you wish to gather around yourselves the majority of the people. There is no
one else to take it up [thunderous applause]. . . .
The banner of national independence and national
sovereignty has been thrown overboard. There is no doubt that it is up to you,
the representatives of communist and democratic parties, to raise this banner
and to carry it forward if you want to become the leading force of nations.
There is no one else to take it up [thunderous applause].
After Stalin's death, the foreign policy of the new
administration changed markedly, and its leaders returned to their own circles:
to the old Russian aspiration to become a world power, even to become a
superpower, but not to the aspiration to supremacy over the entire world.[36]
The new leaders' return to an old Russian policy could be
seen not only within the country, as cutbacks in defense expenditures were
initiated, but in foreign policy as well: in the summer of 1953 the war in
Korea was halted and relations with Yugoslavia began to normalize,[37] in 1955 Soviet troops pulled out of Austria, and in the
same years the U.S.S.R. made a bold foreign policy move when it announced that
it had no territorial claims against Turkey. All of these actions were
accompanied by a shift in the conception of mutual relations between the
U.S.S.R. and Western countries. Instead of the earlier notion that a third
world war would bring victory to the communists, the new administration adopted
the Western point of view that, in the event of a third world war, there would
be no victor. In Soviet terminology, this new policy was called peaceful
coexistence among countries with different sociopolitical systems.
It is curious to note that the new Soviet administration
announced its new focus in foreign affairs rather quickly, literally a month
and a half after Stalin's death. This was demonstrated in the unprecedented
publication in Pravda, on 25
April 1953 of the complete text of President Eisenhower's address to the
American Society of Newspaper Publishers of 16 April 1953. Even the following
passage was not cut from the text:
We know that the death of Josef Stalin marks the end of an
era. During the course of his uncommon thirty-year reign, the Soviet empire
expanded and now stretches from the Baltic Sea to the Sea of Japan, having
established its supremacy over 800 million people.
The Soviet system created by Stalin and his predecessors
was engendered by World War I. It endured World War II, demonstrating
persistence and often striking courage. It has survived to see the threat of a
third world war.
Now a new administration has come to power in the Soviet
Union. Its ties to the past however strong they may be cannot bind it
completely. Its future depends to a significant degree on the administration
itself.
As far as I can remember, at least during the course of the
past forty years, the complete text of an address by a Western leader (given
outside the territory of the U.S.S.R.) has never been published. And what's
more, on the day President Eisenhower's address was published, the entire first
page of Pravda was dedicated to a commentary on the text of the address.
As is apparent from the passages from the commentary cited below, the Soviet
administration, trying to save face, guided public opinion to believe that it
was accepting many of President Eisenhower's suggestions as a result not of
shifts in their own policy but primarily as a result of a change in the United
States' foreign policy.
We do not intend to participate in a discussion with the
president on his rather strange statement about the end of a particular era in
Soviet policy. But we cannot help expressing some surprise over his conclusion
that the government of the U.S.S.R. should dispense with continuity in its
foreign policy, the success of which has been proven by the entire course of
international development.
If one associates the beginning or the end of an era with
the appearance of new faces at the head of the administration, we can with much
justification speak of the end of an era in U.S. policy in connection with the
Eisenhower administration's accession to power. But for some reason, the new
president himself unreservedly defends the policies of his predecessor, whom in
his time, particularly during the election campaign, he often criticized and
not without reason.
Numerous gestures of good will, which according to
Eisenhower should attest to the new Soviet administration's striving for peace,
were quickly carried out. I have in mind the halt of the war in Korea and the
withdrawal of occupying forces from Austria.
Of course it can be said that the change in the pace of the
Russian empire's expansion is a secondary matter, that the main issue is the
Soviet Union's goal of world supremacy as stated in the communist ideology.
However, it seems to me that this is not the case.
I have already addressed the issue of the communist
ideology. Now, in reference to the pace of the empire's expansion, I would like
to propose the following analogy from the sphere of physics. We know that the
transformation of a substance from one form into another, for example from a
plasma into a gas, from a gas into a liquid, from a liquid into a solid, is a
result of change of the speed of motion of the molecules of which the substance
is composed. But it turns out that change in speed brings about so called phase
transitions, which correspond to the changes indicated in the composition of
the substance. We know from a practical point of view just how important the
differentiation of these phases is, as for each of them it is necessary to
utilize an appropriate technology: that which is suitable for the processing of
liquid is not appropriate for the processing of a solid body.
If we use this analogy in order to observe the issue of
imperial tradition in Russia, it can be said that the transformation from a
policy of domination to a policy of world leadership was a phasal
transformation. This can be seen not only in foreign policy, in relations with
Western countries, but also within the empire and inside the U.S.S.R. in particular.
These changes are associated with the name Nikita Sergeyevich Khrushchev.
During his administration, Khrushchev conducted the
humanitarian action of politically rehabilitating more than twenty million
people, although many of them posthumously (here and later I will be referring
to Roy Medvedev's book Khrushchev, [Benson: Chalidze Publ.,1986]); he
debunked Stalin, one of the cruelest tyrants in history; he freed the
population from the Stalinist terror, providing politically inert people with
the opportunity "to die in their own beds" (I say this without any
kind of irony, since one of the distinctive features of tyranny is people's
real fear that they will have no control over their own chances to "die in
one's own bed").
Khrushchev took "parcels" (the system Stalin
introduced of untaxable second and third salaries) away from the elite and
changed the Stalinist law that forbade workers to leave their place of
employment.
Khrushchev concentrated on significantly improving the
Soviet people's standard of living, alleviating the hunger problem inherited by
many regions from the Stalin years, and he was not afraid to purchase grain
from abroad.
Khrushchev, overcoming the opposition of the military,
carried out a number of measures directed at cutbacks in the size of the army,
from approximately 6 million people at the end of Stalin's life, to 2.4 million
in the middle of 1961 (pp. 183--84), and he made cuts in the production of
large, above-water vessels.
In addition, Khrushchev did more than a little to injure
the Soviet economy. The Councils of National Economy, which he created in 1957,
were not at all successful from an economic point of view, but they were useful
from the standpoint of bolstering Khrushchev's personal power: these councils
were under the jurisdiction of the Regional Committees of the Party, where
Khrushchev had considerable support. The inculcation of corn everywhere, the
struggle with grassland agriculture, the huge investment in virgin lands, the
attempt to outdo America in the per capita production of meat and dairy
products and other "artistry"
brought huge losses to the country's economy.
Khrushchev
maintained and expanded the empire using the method of reward and punishment.
Under Khrushchev, the rights of the individual republics were significantly
broadened and the policy of Russian
domination was markedly decreased; this was particularly noticeable in that the
phraseology about the Russian "big brother" disappeared from Soviet
propaganda almost completely. Similar relaxations also occurred in the
relations with countries in the third circle of the empire. According to
Medvedev (although in my opinion he exaggerates a bit, to put it lightly),
under Khrushchev "the degree of freedom that the socialist countries had
in resolving their own domestic and foreign issues grew significantly, and
these countries were now able to participate in the international arena not as
satellites, but as allies of the U.S.S.R." (p. 106).
In the meantime, in October of 1955 the Warsaw Pact was
formed, and in the same year (1956) that Stalin was denounced (after his
unmasking), Khrushchev brutally squelched the Hungarian revolution and then
clandestinely assassinated its leaders. Khrushchev sharply increased financing
for new types of weapons: nuclear missiles and atomic submarines.
Khrushchev's
main contribution to the Russian empire was that he created a new, fourth circle of the empire. Russia
had traditionally expanded its domain along its borders; even Russia's having
acquired land in North America does not contradict this statement.
Stalin
mainly conquered territories having a border with the U.S.S.R., with the
exception of Yugoslavia and Spain. Perhaps the reason Stalin so quickly
disencumbered himself of Spain was the difficulty of ruling this distant
country in case the communists succeeded.
Khrushchev
was the first Russian "tsar" to begin a constant policy of converting
Russia into an overseas empire. Russia had always had the desire to be an
overseas empire, but could not afford it during the period when England,
France, Germany, the Netherlands, Spain, and Portugal divided much of the rest
of the world between themselves. Russia's emphasis was on a land-by-land army;
Russia did not have a navy comparable to the other empires of Europe.
In
the 1950s, the world situation was radically different. On the one hand, the
Soviet Union had become a highly developed industrial society with a large
fleet and a long-distance air force and missiles. On the other hand, after the
dissolution of the major colonial empires, only one nation, the United States,
could oppose the Soviet challenge. Under these conditions, the Soviet leaders
decided to embark on a new stage in the development of the empire: conversion
to an overseas empire. Incursions into Egypt, Indonesia, and Cuba in the 1950s
represented the first steps in creating a Soviet overseas empire.
The
Soviet leaders looked in the Third World for countries where the movement for
independence had succeeded, but had ended in authoritarianism (such cases have
been frequent ). The leader of such a movement has usually been anti-West,
because the movement stemmed from the spirit of anticolonialism. The Soviet
Union called these leaders brother, and were very friendly to them. Such a
leader is a national hero. He can increase his prestige by increasing his
people's standard of living; however,
this demands considerable time and is not compatible with dictatorship. The
most effective way for such a leader to increase his prestige is through
military expansion. The Soviet Union is ready to help him with weapons,
advisers, and so on. Then, the climax:
the leader begins to implement his aggressive agenda; however, his
enemies might be powerful and supported by the West, so the aggressor faces
possible defeat. The Soviet Union is afraid to interfere directly; the leader
changes from a friend of the Soviet Union to an enemy. This leader's resultant
hostility toward the Soviet Union can last a short time, or a long time. This three-stage process describes the
relations between the Soviet Union and autocratic political regimes in the
Third World (such as Egypt, Indonesia, Cuba, etc.) over the last thirty years.
It should be noted that economic aid by the Soviet Union to
Third World countries plays a role that is a secondary to military aid. It only
partially helps to develop the economy and the culture of these countries; the
Soviet industrial projects are usually of low quality. However, the leaders of
these countries regard this help from the point of view of increasing their own
prestige; this means that the leader' s interest lies in grandiose economic
projects that can involve him, and thus immortalize his name. The economic
efficiency of these projects is secondary. The fate of such projects is well
known (the Aswan Dam project in Egypt is a typical example).
Thus, Khrushchev's policies were extremely contradictory.
From one point of view, there was a rejection of the policy aiming for world
domination and a proclamation of the policy of being a world leader within the
circle of other world leaders. This was accompanied by endeavors to increase
the U.S.S.R.'s economic development,
including consideration of the population's needs. Simultaneously, the
population was stimulated as the insane terror of Stalinist times was removed
(the rehabilitation of hundreds of thousands of political prisoners, a marked
decrease in the number of prisoners in labor camps, etc.). On the other hand,
these stirrings did not mark a halt in the growth of the empire or in the
buildup of its military might; they simply marked a significant decrease in the
pace of its growth compared to the Stalinist period. It is essential to
remember that during this phase, not only were expenditures on new types of
weapons, particularly nuclear missiles and atomic submarines, not scaled down,
they were increased.
These measures had their effect, and for a time, they
increased the nation's potential. However, the political structure of the
Soviet system and its methods of authoritarian rule were preserved in their
entirety, defense expenditures gradually began to increase again, the
exhaustion of the country's resources continued, and people gradually became
used to this new life-style; a certain degree of political toughening on the
part of the regime from the mid-1960s on led to many of the people becoming
even more cynical. In the end, all of this predestined the drop in the nation's
potential and the systemic stagnation of the late 1970's. Also, during this
period of Khrushchev's reforms, a particular group of people developed who were
anxious about the fate of their country. They embodied all the contradictions
of the Khrushchev era, and they are now the inspiration behind the
restructuring of Soviet society.
In subsequent years, Soviet leadership pursued its imperial
policy. Even at a time of detente when Brezhnev was in power, the empire was
held together by rather cruel means (the strangling of Czechoslovakia in 1968),
and it even expanded (the invasion of Angola in the 1960s). Brezhnev's rule
from this point of view culminated in the Russian invasion of Afghanistan at
the end of 1979.
Gorbachev took over the country at a time when its size
makes it difficult to sustain, much less expand, the empire. In the next
chapter, I want to consider some of the problems encountered by Gorbachev along
this path, first and foremost being the the country's militaristic orientation,
a factor largely responsible for its exhaustion and the current crisis.
Notes and References
Notes and References
5
The Military Imperial
Orientation of Soviet Society
In the past,
the creative energies of the entire Soviet society went into the conduct of an
aggressive foreign policy and the continual accumulation of military power. The
signs of a pervasive militarization lay ready at hand anywhere in the U.S.S.R.:
propaganda about military events, compulsory military service, and so on.
Only recently,
after Gorbachev came to power, has this policy been opened up for public
discussion, and certain official statements have been made about a shift from
an offensive to a defensive strategy in Soviet military doctrine. A serious
debate was launched on the issue of a voluntary professional armed forces. The
war in Afghanistan has been criticized, albeit halfheartedly. Only time will
reveal the true significance of these initiatives.
In this chapter I would like to concentrate
on certain economic aspects of Soviet militarization. I will present some
methodological observations on this issue, deliberately avoiding any
entanglement with statistics, since the latter require a separate, complex
inquiry. I only want to note in passing that the U.S.S.R. obviously does not
publish statistics on this topic. When Western economists travel to the
U.S.S.R. in order to research an issue never before researched in the U.S.S.R.,
one has to listen to Professor Vladimir Treml of Duke University in order to
appreciate how hungrily Soviet colleagues pounce upon what has been declared
"top secret information."
To be sure, there have been some minor
exceptions lately: statements about the cost of the Afghan war, Gorbachev's
pronouncement concerning direct Soviet military expenditures at the Congress of
People's Deputies, and deputy Nikolaj Shmelev's remarks at the same forum on
Soviet help to the Caribbean countries.[38]
The question of the cost of the empire is an
extremely interesting topic for Western Sovietologists. The RAND corporation
have recently published research on this issue[39]. Interesting calculations regarding
direct Soviet military expenditures were done by Igor I. Birman.[40]
The
structure of expenditures on the maintenance of the empire is multifaceted. A
significant amount is extended to the countries in the fourth circle of the
empire, Cuba in particular. Economic relations with the third circle of the
empire are rather complicated: there is very contradictory data concerning the
economic exchanges between the U.S.S.R. and Eastern Europe, and which side
benefits from these exchanges. Whatever the case, it is obvious that the the
U.S.S.R. derives the greatest benefit from the Eastern European countries by
imposing a huge military burden on them, forcing them to share the costs of
imperial expansionism.
Huge
as the U.S.S.R.'s expenditures on the maintenance of the imperial periphery
are, the lion's share of the empire's costs lies in Soviet economy's military
orientation.
The economy
that has been created in the Soviet Union is a military economy. This is
not an easy point to prove, if only because one needs a good deal of
documentary evidence related to Soviet military expenditures. I will, however,
provide my own definition of military economy, which I know to be somewhat
different from the conventional one.
Let us first take two extreme situations. On
the one hand, there is a peaceful tribe of shepherds, isolated in hard-to-reach
mountains. The notion of peace economy fully applies to this tribe, with its
war expenditures being equal to zero. The other extreme is a country in a state
of deadly conflict with its enemy - as was, for example, the situation of the
U.S.S.R. at the time of the war with Nazi Germany. In this case the nation can
be said to operate under a war economy: practically all expenditures, from the
food for the workers to the production of tanks, are war related. Between these
two extremes there is a wide spectrum of different degrees of militarization.
The
Soviet economy was organized in a manner that rendered it prepared for war and,
ultimately, an offensive war. The goal was clear enough and everything else was
subordinate to it. A system emerged which drew up plans for the nation's
development and administrative methods and oversaw the realization of these
plans.
Such is the functional nature of the
Soviet economy.
If we now look
structurally at Soviet military expenditures, they turn out to be all
the country's expenditures minus the production costs of consumer goods and
services, which would be cut back in the event of a war. To develop this point
further, let us divide Soviet military expenditures into three parts: direct, conjugated
and indirect expenditures.
The category
of direct expenditures includes direct outlays for arms production,
construction of military installations, and payments to military personnel.
Apparently, this part of military expenditures is reflected in the official
Soviet statistics under the heading of the "defense budget." The
statistics, however, conceal direct defense expenditures for the construction
of new arms factories, and most importantly huge outlays for scientific
research and design work not directly under the auspices of the Ministry of
Defense.
Conjugated military expenditures are
the additional costs of peacetime production called for by the need to sustain
a militarized economy. For example, from the military point of view it is necessary
to give priority to tractors whose production can be easily converted into the
production of tanks. These tractors should have tracks, a lot of power, and
need not last very long. For many years the production of tractors with tracks
predominated, even though it is generally more efficient to use tractors on
wheels if only because they do less damage to the soil.
By indirect expenditures I understand
the costs associated with the nation's general militaristic orientation, that
is, with the policy of maintaining an economic potential for the satisfaction
of defense needs. The military-economic potential includes such items as steel,
oil, coal, steel cutting equipment, all kinds of transportation equipment and
facilities, etc. In this case, the objective of steel production, for instance,
is a greater output of the same. These expenditures are extremely difficult to
calculate but they make up a huge part of the defense burden.
From
the standpoint of the process, the Soviet militarized economy faces the
task of finding reasonable adjustments to peacetime production. The adjustments
consist mainly in using the available capacities in a manner that minimizes the
costs of their possible rapid conversion to military production. The need to
produce consumer goods in a militarized economy is dictated by at least two
reasons: on the one hand, it is important that these means be utilized, if only
for the workers to gain some experience, and, on the other, it is essential to
provide the population with consumer goods in order to stimulate their interest
in work. I reiterate that this is nothing more than an adjustment of a military
economy to peacetime needs.
Thus,
in the U.S.S.R. we are dealing with a rather entrenched system - one which has
it own particular logic - of a military economy during peacetime. Of course, in
managing this sort of integrated economic system the usual difficulties arise,
and certain economic and political issues must be resolved. Problem-solving,
however, often takes a rather perverse form.
From
the standpoint of genesis, the Soviet militarized economy has, from the
onset of industrialization in the 1930s, been perpetuating the traditions of
Russia's economic development, which also exhibited a very strong military
bias.
There
is another possible classification of Soviet military expenditures based on the
time factor. Thus, we can distinguish the tactical costs (direct expenditures
on arms and personnel, minus a large sum for direct military research and
developement) related to the first strike capability that can be used on a
short notice, ultimately in the very first hours of hostilities, and the
strategic costs ( indirect expenditures on building a military-economic
potential, outlays for research and development without immediate military
applications) incurred with a view to gaining a long-range military advantage.
Between the tactical and the strategic costs there is a separate category of
intermediate military costs that are largely equivalent to conjugated military
expenditures, since a rapid convertibility of industry could become a telling
consideration as early as the first few months of the war.
The impact of militarization upon the
structure of the Soviet economy
Dilemma in the Amount of Production of
Different Consumer Goods.
In the
U.S.S.R. a major role in the planning process is played by the division of
industry into groups A and B. Group A involves the production of the means of
production, i.e. capital goods. Theoretically, any intermediate commodity and
any unfinished consumer good are "means of production." Thus, all
processes except for the final production of consumer goods should be regarded
as production of means of production. Group B includes branches of light
industry which produce consumer goods and intermediate products. This division
of industry makes sense because of differences in the structure of production
of various consumer goods.
Among consumer goods Soviet planners favor
those that employ the technologies easily convertible to the production of military
goods. During a war the production of consumer goods decreases rapidly.
Production capacities for consumer goods are differently convertible. The least
convertible are the capacities involved in the production of food and clothing
(that is, nondurables), which are classified as Group B activities. The most
convertible are the capacities for the production of durable goods such as cars
and radio-electronics. These are classified as Group A activities.
One of the
most surprising phenomenon in Soviet economic history is a relative (and
absolute) decrease in the production of some non-durable goods. This was
particularly true of the period of industrialization in the 1930s. Even now
this process is in evidence, but not to the same extent as before. If one
compares the production of consumer goods in Russia before and after the
revolution, one will notice a tremendous growth in the production of durable
consumer goods (there were practically none before the revolution) but a very
slow growth in the production of important nondurable goods.
Although there
was a shortage of important consumer goods such as food and clothing, the
government has increased the production of durable goods such as television
sets. In the beginning of the 1970s the ministry producing televisions insisted
that their output be increased. This was truly an unprecedented case in
the history of Soviet planning: an industrial ministry asking for a larger
plan. In the Soviet Union managers lean over backwards "to get a smaller
plan" since their well-being depends on their being able to fulfill it.
The demand to increase the plan for the production of televisions was motivated
by the desire to increase the capacity for the production of electronic goods -
a capacity with ready military applications. Consumer demand for more
television sets was weak for a simple reason: the price of a new set was
approximately equal to two months' average salary. Families with sets did not
rush to replace them. Another factor was the tradition of a country with a low
standard of living where durable goods are typically not thrown away. Families
without sets could not afford them any more then than they could before.
As it
happened, the effort to increase production was largely successful. To make it
successful the planners had to alter the typical methods of Soviet marketing
and introduce some western practices. In effect a trade-in market was created.
For every old television traded in (practically all old sets were discarded), a
certain sum was paid which could be used only as a
downpayment for a new television which could be bought on credit.
Dilemma in Production of Various Capital
Goods.
Since the
capacity to produce means of production is versatile to some extent, the
U.S.S.R. first develops capacities that can be easily convertible to arms
production. This process was clearly in evidence in the 1930s. The
industrialization that was then undertaken was motivated by the decision to
increase the production of those means of production which could be used to
produce arms.
The
"tractor-fertilizer" controversy is a case in point. Soviet
agricultural scientists in the early 1930s proposed to increase the production
of chemical fertilizers. The technology of fertilizer production, however, is
of little potential military value. On the other hand, in order to use
mechanized technology in agriculture effectively, it is necessary to have
qualified operators, fuel, repair services, etc. The U.S.S.R. had none. The
capacities for the production of agricultural machines could, however, be
easily converted to the production of tanks, grenade launchers, etc. As a
result, during the period of pre-war industrialization, the output of mineral
fertilizers was very low and the output of tractors was rather high. The results
for Soviet agriculture are well known.
After Stalin,
the situation gradually changed. The output of mineral fertilizer increased
step by step with the output of tractors. An interesting question is how
sensible these policies are for the development of Soviet agriculture in light
of how much they are determined by the preferences of the Soviet
military-industrial complex.
Dilemma in the Production of Goods of
Different Quality.
Soviet
commodities usually do not meet world standards of quality. Such a situation
has an effect on trade between the Soviet Union and Western countries.
One of the
reasons for a comparatively low quality of Soviet non-military goods is the
orientation of production toward the fast conversion to military goods. An
increase in the quality of goods may require technological processes not used
at all in the production of arms. This is because higher quality usually
requires (a) technological operations and equipment which are not necessary in
the production of lower quality goods, (b) technological operations and
equipment which largely can not be converted to the production of arms.
Thus in the
production of many types of goods a dilemma arises: whether to increase quality
and consequently sacrifice capacities that could be used in the production of
arms. The dilemma is obvious in the production of tractors; it is also
characteristic of the production of planes, automobiles, etc.
In designing a
tractor, for example, the following question arise: How long should it last?
During the war, tanks did not last more than a few months. In comparison a
tractor may last for years. In order to produce long-lasting tractors, extra
investments are required. For example, ball-bearings, an important part of
tractors, may require extra technological operations for polishing, etc. These
operations require considerable financing but, in the time of war, the
resultant equipment is not necessary.
Another aspect of tractor quality is
repair. The lifetime of tanks during war is very short; a large number of spare
parts is not needed. For the production of tanks, the balance between
mechanical and assembly workshops is different from that for the production of
tractors. It is not surprising, therefore, that in the Soviet Union there is a
chronic shortage of spare parts for tractors. The factories that produce
tractors manufacture only a small percentage of spares which the number of tractors would dictate. Chronic
shortages of spare parts result because, on the one hand, a relatively great
need for spare parts follows from a low quality and short life of machine
components and, on the other hand, because the structure of capacities at
tractor factories is mainly determined by their conversion potential for the
production of tanks.
Shortages of
spare parts sent by the tractor factories have to be compensated for in other
ways. An active "compensatory" role is played by provincial party
bodies, which are responsible for the delivery of agricultural products. Party
bodies force enterprises of different branches of industry in their region to
produce spare parts for agricultural machines. The additional expenditures of
producing spare parts at non-specialized enterprises are very large.
Sometimes, too, heads of collective farms illegally purchase spare parts from
producers. The additional sources of supply notwithstanding, the amount of
spare parts do not fill the need of the agricultural community. One result is
that about 40 percent of tractors are not in working order: they are
cannibalized. The situation feeds upon itself: by cannibalizing some tractors
one can supply a certain number of working tractors with spare parts.
A few remarks
are in order concerning Soviet metal-cutting equipment. Statistical abstracts
do not publish data on the structure of metal cutting tools. However, these
tools are designed mainly for rough processing. As a resullt, shortages of
equipment for precise processing often
arise in machine building for light industry. For example, modern looms require
equipment of a high degree of precision. The lack of this kind of equipment in
Soviet textile machine factories stems from the fact that most of it goes to
military aircraft factories, which end up producing the looms.
Recall that in
the Soviet Union a great deal of information is classified, and bureaucracy is
universal, so that to change the capacities of military factories to
nonmilitary production is very complicated and therefore very often not done.
Meanwhile, enterprises that produce many kinds of agricultural machinery and
equipment for light industry can very successfully convert their capacities in
wartime to producing large quantities of unsophisticated weapons, such as
grenade launchers. And, hence, they are favored.
Dilemma in the Design of New Productis
Versus the Development of New Technologies.
In the
manufacture of weapons, (or any other products) it is useful to distinguish the
design stage from the stage of technological implementation. The Soviet Union
has reached a relatively high level of sophistication in the design of many
kinds of weapons, but lags far behind the West in new weapons technologies. The
disparity can be partly explained by the fact that while the types of weapons
produced number in hundreds, different kinds of equipment and technological
operations required by the production process can easily number in tens of
thousands.
Soviet leaders
prefer to spend their resources on the design of the most advanced types of
weapons. The design process is organized pretty efficiently. For every specific
new weapon system there is at least one leading design bureau. Each bureau has
an experimental factory for the manufacture of
prototypes. After a trial
period, the prototype is sent to a main factory for line production. The
factory and the bureau together develop several technological versions of the
design for line production. Afterwards, the design and the technology are
passed on to other factories for large-scale production.
To set up a
similar system to design new technologies and equipment requires a huge amount of resources. In all branches of industry in the Soviet
Union, especially in the military branches, one can see large technological
research institutes. There is a separate set of bureaus for the design of general
- purpose equipment. The specialized bureaus are concentrated directly in those
branches of industry that use the equipment.
It is a poor
experimental base that is the weak point of Soviet technological design
process. Not only is the investment in such a base costly; Soviet experimental workshops
and enterprises are not being fully utilized for their main purpose. Current
production plans always enjoy a top priority in the Soviet Union, and the
ministry (if the enterprise is experimental) or the factory (if it is an
experimental workshop) demand from experimental enterprises (workshops) to
concentrate first on meeting the current needs, not on research and
development.
The quality
gap in the design of weapon systems and technologies results in greater weapons
costs, and hinders the development of advanced systems.
It is well
known that the more specialized the equipment, the lower the unit costs of
production because, for example, specialized equipment may be easier to
automate. But specialized equipment could hinder improvements and changes in
commodities because it is more expensive to alter than less specialized
equipment.
Most Soviet
batch production factories are ordered to use general-purpose equipment. This
equipment makes it very easy to go from one product to another. Such flexibility,
however, is associated with very great unit costs. At Soviet mass production
enterprises, there is a large percentage of specialized equipment. This
equipment restricts the possibilities of product improvement but enables the
manufacturer to produce goods at a relatively low cost per unit.
The
differences in truck and aircraft manufacturing illustrate these contrasting
cases. In the main workshops of Soviet truck factories the proportion of
automatic and semiautomatic equipment has reached approximately two-thirds of
the total. This automatic equipment has a very low level of flexibility. It
has, as a result, become a hindrance to the development of large-scale production
of new types of trucks. The fact that truck designs in the Soviet Union are
modified so infrequently is in part due to the fact that it is very expensive
to change the equipment. It is noteworthy that stagnation in Soviet truck
production technologies could become a major bottleneck if and when it is
decided to convert truck factories to the production of military goods.
Aircraft
manufacturing in the U.S.S.R. is another case altogether. There is no system to
mass produce a counterpart nonmilitary product. In general, the manufacturing
of aircraft is characterized by medium or short production runs. The share of automatic equipment at aircraft
factories is very small. General-purpose equipment predominates, and it is
comparatively easy to shift to the production of new kinds of products. The
existence of such equipment gives Soviet aircraft factories the ability to
adapt very quickly to changes in aircraft design. Little specialization of
equipment and low automation levels, however, result in high unit costs.
One way to
solve this dilemma is to develop aggregate tools, that is, specialized
equipment easily assembled from general-purpose building blocks. Tools can be
assembled and disassembled to meet the factory's changing needs. Even though
the Soviet Union was one of the pioneers in the field of producing aggregate
tools, the introduction of these tools into industry has been relatively
limited. The use of general-purpose equipment is still dominant today.
The general
technological stagnation of Soviet enterprises fuels a great interest that
Soviet leaders have in Western technology. Soviet leaders preferred to spend
their money on new technologies for those branches of industry that historically
had to convert to the production of military goods and, more important, on
technologies that can also be used directly in the production of weapons. For
example, a factory for the production of heavy trucks on the Kama river
(Kamaz), whose technology and equipment was bought mainly from the United
States, produces trucks that can be directly used for military purposes.
Moreover, the production technology for
many parts of these trucks can be used directly for the production of parts for
weapons systems, for example, tanks, mobile missile platforms, and so on.
Dilemma in the Implementation of
Economically Effective Technologies.
Technologies
can vary with respect to their vulnerability in the event of war. An
economically more efficient technology could be more vulnerable in the
military sense.
During the
Stalin era, the railroad transport system primarily used steam engines. The
railroad system was considered to be the most important transport system and
was developed rapidly. Steam engines, in spite of their relatively low economic
effectiveness, were a more effective type of locomotive in the military sense
because they could run on many types of fuel. Diesel engines were considered
more vulnerable: they can run only on a
special fuel. In addition, in the Stalin era it was thought that, in case of war, oil resources should be
saved for airplanes and tanks since they can not use any other fuel. Engines using electricity were not convenient
for the military since one break in an electrical line would cripple a large
part of a railway electric engines. Therefore, they were not widely used in
Stalin's railroad transport system.
In the post-Stalin
period, the structure of railway engines was radically changed in a very short
time. Most of the locomotives now have diesel or electric engines. Though the
steam engines are no longer in use, they are still being kept as a war reserve.
Their number is currently much less than that of diesel and electric
locomotives.
Dilemma in the Allocation of Industrial
Installations.
The location
of enterprises in the U.S.S.R. is determined to a large extent by the desire to
secure military invulnerability.
From the
military point of view, the question of locating enterprises in the U.S.S.R.
centers around the problem of distributing the production between the western
and eastern regions. It is argued that such a balance will make the supply of
military goods relatively more secure in the event of war.
In Soviet economic literature of the 1920s and
1930s, animated military discussions were carried out regarding the relative
importance of economic goals. Unfortunately, many works written on then-current
problems have been lost. (They were simply removed from libraries as works
written by "enemies of the people.") The literature that remains,
however, we can get the essence of the problem.
In comparing
predictions presented in the 1920s and 1930s with what actually occurred, it is
interesting to note the arguments by which economists of the 1930s justified
themselves. Thus, for example, Berezov, argued that the development of the
eastern regions would be advantageous even from an economic standpoint.
In spite of
economic inefficiency, it was decided to develop the eastern regions for
military reasons. World War II showed that these regions played a decisive role
in securing the U.S.S.R.'s victory, and that the right decision had been made.
A second question remains open: were large parallel investments in western
regions wise? The simultaneity of these parallel investments determined the
overwhelming pace of industrialization, with all its negative consequences.
During World
War II, the U.S.S.R. lost a large part of its industrial base when the western
regions were quickly occupied. Part of the equipment was evacuated to the east,
but a great portion of the capital invested in western regions was lost. In
spite of these losses, the Soviet Union not only won the war, but also emerged
in a strengthened military posture. This suggests that parallel investments
were unnecessary even from a military perspective.
The questions
of the 1930s remain alive today: the debates concerning the construction of the
Bratsk hydroelectric station, the Baikal-Amur railroad, and similar projects in
eastern regions, or over huge investments in agriculture in the central regions
mentioned in the current five year plan, always touch upon the issues left
unresolved in the controversies of the 1930s.
The factors
taken into account in allocating industrial installations may not make any
sense if we ignore military considerations.
Toward the end
of the 1940s, the important question of whether to organize the mining of
lignite in the western U.S.S.R. (in the Smolensk area, for example,) was
raised. It was not economically effecient to mine low-calorie coal in difficult
conditions. Miners' wages are among the highest in the U.S.S.R.. In political
terms, the party regarded miners as a group most devoted to Soviet power. The
lack of developed industry in this area and the corresponding structure of the
population were thought to have aided the enemy's advance through the country.
A military
orientation has permeated the fabric of the Soviet economy. It exerts a strong
impact upon the ability of the economic system to improve itself; the
introduction of an effective market mechanism must be practically ruled out
with such a strong militaristic bias in the economy. The point is that a
monopoly of producers as well as of consumers (monopsony) precludes an
effective market mechanism. The government in a peace-oriented economy in peace
time has a monopoly upon the consumption only of the final products required by
the army: tanks, airplanes, military uniforms, and so on. The volume of
consumption of these goods in peacetime is not sufficient to strongly deform
the market. In a militarized economy, even in peacetime, the government must
oversee the convertibility of production capacities and the creation of economic
potential based upon such primary products as steel, oil, coal, electricity,
metal-cutting equipment. These considerations force the government to intervene
not only in the acquisition of final products needed by the army but also in
planning the output of capital goods. Otherwise, resources might be diverted
from increasing the output of the required capital goods to increasing the
output of consumer goods. In other words, we can say that the level of control
over the output of capital goods represents a criterion by which we can
recognize a military-oriented economy.
Ways to Change the
Country's Military Orientation
My
remarks here have been brief and necessarily somewhat anecdotal. The foreign
policy of the Soviet Union is in many ways free of the sort of domestic
constraints present in a more democratic society. It exercises a strong and
often dominant influence on economic policy with regard to such things as
output levels, choice of technology, and location of industry, as well as in
overtly allocating large amount of resources to military needs. In so doing it
imposes enormous costs on the Soviet economy in general. For this reason,
Soviet foreign policy should be considered a principal determinant of Soviet
economic affairs and a principal cause of economic problems. In my opinion, the
Soviet Union will be unable to implement any significant changes in the country
or the economy without a major reexamination of its military doctrine, without
rejecting militarized economy.
Nevertheless,
Soviet economists involved in restructuring the economy have underestimated the
crippling impact of the military factor upon economic performance. Even as
progressive a Soviet economist as Nikolaj Shmelev, in his celebrated article
"Payments and Debts" minimizes the significance of this factor when
he addresses the issue of defense expenditure. Here is what he writes on this
topic:
It
is essential to consider clearly that the reason for our difficulties lies not
only and really not so much in the heavy burden of defense expenditure and in
the extremely costly scale of our nation's global responsibility. Given
reasonable expenditures, even remaining material and human resources may be
entirely sufficient for the maintenance of a balanced economy oriented toward technological
progress for the satisfaction of the traditionally modest needs of our
population.[41]
In
order to halt economic stagnation and to guide the economic process in the
direction of stable, long-term development, the first thing Gorbachev may have
to do is to renounce the primary goal of the nation's development: the marked
growth of military power in the name of strengthening and expanding the empire.
From
here, the Soviet Union's most pressing problem is determining what strategy the
nation's leader will adopt. If the problem is presented in its extreme forms,
the following two alternative courses
arise.
The
first is the combinatorial course in which the goal of the nation's development
is to continue to view the strengthening of the military might of the empire as
the nation's top priority. Possible courses of action include (1) decreasing
defense expenditure for a few years in order to use resources, which would then
become available, to update capital, improve the quality of production, and
increase the population's wellbeing; (2) changing the methods by which the
economic system functions and stimulate the population; (3) decreasing foreign
expenditures on the maintenance of the empire.
The
second course is the positional course, in which the purpose of the nation's
development is to create the potential for peacetime development. Possible
courses of action include (1) rejecting the empire; 2) orienting the structure
of production and power to peacetime production; (3) gradually creating a pluralistic, democratic, open system,
with separation of powers; (4) maintaining the level of defense so that it is
adequate should the country be threatened with attack.
The
second course is obvious enough, but it runs counter to the aspirations of the
current leadership. My hypothesis, that Gorbachev aims at strengthening an
autocratic imperial regime using a flexible approach, points to the first
course as a more realistic one.
It
seems to me that the revitalization of the economy, if it is even possible,
will prove to be totally insufficient to overcome the difficulties that have
arisen in the U.S.S.R.; these difficulties are already too serious, because
they have been engendered not by some sort of coincidental fluctuations of
temporary significance, but, as I have said earlier, by the country's military
imperial orientation.
Gorbachev,
as the leader of a large imperial superpower, understands that one of the most
important economic moves for the stimulation of the economy is cutbacks in
exorbitant military spending. The time is right for this, since no one in the
immediate future seems likely to attack the Soviet Union: Western countries
could but do not desire to, while China would like to but is presently unable.
Furthermore, during the 1930s when production was not very high, even under
more temperate domestic policies than Stalin's, it would have been difficult to
reconcile the accumulation of great military power with peaceful needs;
nowadays, when the scale of production in the U.S.S.R. has attained a considerable
level, it is possible under a temperate domestic policy to direct a significant
portion of resources towards peacetime needs while still leaving sufficient
resources for direct defense purposes. It goes without saying that the means
saved from such a reorientation of resources could also be utilized for the
growth of military power.
I
believe that Gorbachev can take decisive action to cut back military
production, to help the exhausted economy, but . . . . This "but"
embodies the crux of the matter. Not only will expenditures on research on the
latest types of armaments (which can be called nonconventional weapons)
not be reduced, they may even be increased. Expenditures on the production of
the usual (that is, conventional ) weapons, may be reduced, as may
expenditures on those types of nuclear missiles that have already become
traditional (which can be called semi-conventional weapons). Under this
type of system the size of the army may decrease noticeably, particularly the
size of construction battalions and traditional types of troops. It is exatly
what was done by Khrushchev in 1957-1959 (See chapter 3 pp.117-118).
Many
supporters of the military will of course protest these cutbacks. But perhaps
they could be told: "We are implementing all these reductions in order to
boost the strength of the country in the future. Do not be afraid that we are
changing the Russian empire's great tradition of strength and expansion. Since
we are preserving the authoritarian state, this is a guarantee that we will
need military strength. Only the introduction of a pluralistic democratic
mechanism with a separation of powers and an open society can pose a threat to
our goals. Only under such a system can military efforts be limited, only under
such a system can the country grow and develop while not resorting to
expansionism. And you must also understand that without reducing defense
expenditures, without reorienting a significant proportion of resources to
peacetime needs today, we will not have a sophisticated industrial base to
fulfil military requirements tomorrow. A certain amount of resources deferred
from defense expenditure, of course, will have to be used for the production of
consumer goods, otherwise we will not be able to stimulate the people to work well."
Then we can expect that a certain number of military men will waver, and
finally agree with the arguments of their senior colleagues, all the more so as
in return for their support they will be rewarded personally with promotions
and the prospects of a speedy succession to positions of power in a healthy
party.
Thus, I
believe that the development policy proposed by Gorbachev is primarily a
political breather, directed toward the preservation and strengthening of the
empire. A respite in the arms race is sure to prove extremely important for the
nation's overall development, particularly if the rejection of expansionism and
a bent toward demilitarization is accomplished in an irreversible manner (while
still taking the real threat of attack, say on the part of China, into
consideration, of course). But in order to change the traditional policy of
Russia's development, considerable effort is required, effort that may prove to
be beyond Gorbachev's strength, and beyond the strength of any of the country's
leaders. Moreover, it is not even known whether there exists a solution to this
problem, if we accurately weigh such a factor as the population's political
culture.
Notes and References
6
The Structure of the Second Imperial Circle
and
How It Might
Change
Diversity of
Cultures in the Soviet Union: The Hierarchy of Regions
The
governance of large societies, of necessity, entails the concept of
decomposition. The basis upon which a societal system is subdivided into a
hierarchy of blocks may be either regional or ministerial. A hierarchy may be
established on the basis of any one of the following three principles: (1)
managerial strengths, that is, the ability to solve various problems that may
arise in the region; (2) technological principles, that is, either the strength
of internal linkages in the region, which can help to reduce the burden on the
higher level of the hierarchy, or the homogeneity of the technological
processes, which helps to concentrate professionals in a certain region to as
great an extent as possible; or (3) social factors, that is, the national and
cultural integrity of the inhabitants of the region. In the Soviet Union, all
of these criteria have been taken into account in the formation of regions. At
the top level of the hierarchy-particularly for the formation of economic
regions-the second criterion was used. The formation of union republics and
autonomous republics was based upon the third criterion. Provinces and
districts were organized on the basis of the first criterion.
The
highest level of the regional hierarchy may be formed on the basis of the type
of ideology accepted by the majority of inhabitants. Ideology means that system
of values by which the majority organizes its behavior. The classification of
ideologies utilized in this analysis is based on the classification of personalities
proposed by Russell Ackoff and Fred Emery.[42] This
classification is based upon an analysis of the personality of an individual
in terms of the two relations that can exist between him and his environment:
(1) the extent to which his environment affects him (environmental
responsiveness), and (2) the extent to which he affects his environment (environmental
affectiveness). From the standpoint of an individual's response to his
environment, one can distinguish between an objectivert (a man
responsive to his environment), and a subjectivert (one who is not
responsive to his environment). From the standpoint of an individual affecting
his environment, we can distinguish an externalizer (a man who is
inclined to change his environment in accordance with his needs), and an internalizer
(one who, by changing his internal world, adapts himself to the
environment). By classifying personalities
in these two terms (that is, his individual's response to the environment and
his affect on the environment), four personality types can now be
distinguished. Two of them accordingly represent extreme cases, that is, the
completely introverted personality type, a subjective internalizer, or the completely
extraverted personality type, an objective externalizer. Two other personality
types represent intermediary cases: the objective internalizer and the
subjective externalizer.
My
personal opinion is that in the Soviet Union three ideological types prevail:
subjective externalistic, objective externalistic, and objective internalistic.
The subjective internalistic ideology is also to be found in the Soviet Union,
but it does not prevail among any of its national groups. The Baltic people
could be characterized typically as subjective externalizers, Slavic people as
objective externalizers, and Moslems as objective internalizers. In conformity
with this classification of the Soviet population one can distinguish regions:
first, objective externalistic, encompassing the present-day territory of the
Russian Federation, the Ukraine, White Russia and the Caucasus (with the
exception of Azerbaijan); second, subjective externalistic, that is, the
Baltic Republics; third, objective internalistic including the territory of
Central Asia and Azerbaijan.
In
Soviet literature there is no such classification of the regions, but its
acceptance enables us to immediately detect differences in the development
processes in different parts of the Soviet Union. In the first place, there is
a noticeable difference in rates of population growth among various national
groups (see Table 6.1).
Without
stopping to elaborate the relationship between ideology and rate of population
growth, let me draw attention to certain of the consequences of this
relationship. The rapid growth of the Moslem population in the Soviet Union
compared to other groups has first and foremost raised the issue of how to
maintain a high rate of growth for Soviet industry. It is known that Moslems
traditionally have not been technological innovators. The industrialization of
the Moslem regions of the U.S.S.R. was accomplished primarily by Slavic
peoples. Even at the present time the Slavic population plans an essential role
in these regions. Table 6.2 illustrates the role of the non-Moslem population
in Moslem regions[43].
Slavic
people predominate among the nonnative population of Moslem regions and are
actively involved in industry, occupying a disproportionately high proportion
of the skilled jobs. This fact must be taken into account in the analysis of
the Soviet experience of industrialization in Moslem regions, particularly
given the fact that large territories with Moslem populations are now entering
the industrialization stage and attempting to imitate the Soviet experience.
It
should also be noted that the rapid growth of the Moslem population is creating
problems for the Soviet Army. Moslems traditionally are less prepared to use
modern weapons, and furthermore, are ill equipped to serve in the colder
regions of Russia. (Let me remind the reader that in accordance with the
pre-Revolutionary Russian tradition, individuals from one region are drafted
into the army and sent to serve in other regions. This system was designed to
enhance the political stability of a multinational empire, and its usage
continues in the present-day Soviet Union.[44])
Demographic
changes in the Baltic regions raised other difficulties for further
industrialization. The Baltic republics are a potential source of workers, who
are necessary for industrialization to proceed, but the growth rate of the
Baltic population is low.
The continuous
growth of the nonnative population in these areas threatens the Baltic peoples
with the loss of even that limited degree of political autonomy that they now
possess. The sad experience of the disbanding of the Karelo-Finnish Republic in
the 1950s because it lacked a sufficient percentage of native population serves
as a constant reminder of what the Soviet leaders can do to union republics. In
light of this, the Baltic peoples view with trepidation the further
industrialization of their region. As
is apparent from table 6.3, the proportion of native people in these republics
is already rather low. I cannot vouch for the validity of the following
information, but it is nevertheless interesting in that it illustrates Baltic
people's attitude to the industrialization of their region by the introduction
of more Slavic peoples. My Estonian colleagues told me that, at the end of the
1960s, the leaders of Estonia, during discussions with the central government
concerning the future industrialization of this region, said that Germans would
be sent to Estonia. The Germans under discussion were those who lived in the
Altai region and in Central Asia; whose number totaled 1,800,000. As is well
known, these Germans live in the regions to which they were deported from the
German Volga Autonomous Republic soon after Hitler attacked the Soviet Union.
The
next level in the hierarchy of regions is formed on the basis of the
nationality of the native population and on the basis of whether the region has
a border with a foreign country. It is
on this level of the hierarchy that the union republics are formed. There are
fifteen such republics, which form the main regions in the Soviet political and
economic system. Economic relations between the central government and the
regions represented by the union republics are institutionalized to a large
degree; that is, the regions have central committees of the Communist party
(with the exception of the Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic
[RSFSR]), councils of ministers, and so forth. However, the recognition of the
union republic as the major regional subdivision results in great planning
problems. Some republics (such as the RSFSR) are much too large and others
(such as the Baltic republics) are much too small. For example, the population
of RSFSR in 1987 was 281,690,000 and of Estonia, 1,556,000. The result is that
for planning purposes the territory of the Soviet Union is subdivided into
so-called economic regions. These regions are formed on the basis of their
internal economic linkages or the homogeneity of the conditions under which
they function. There are eighteen of these economic regions in the Soviet Union
including, among others, the Central non black earth region, Volga, Ural,
Western Siberia, Baltic, Caucasus, and Central Asia. However, these economic
regions are not supported by managerial institutions. Khrushchev made an attempt
to support these regions by the introduction of several institutions, such
as planning institutions. However, his
ideas were never brought to complete fruition.
The
existence of union republics also creates severe political problems, which are
linked with the growth of nationalism and these republics' aspirations to
become independent. The growth of nationalism is aggravated by the development
of an intelligentsia among the various
national groups, persons who are better able to express the feelings of their
people and to find a way to fight for their independence. This process is
accelerated by Russian chauvinism, which is opposed by the native peoples of
the union republics. In the political struggle with Russian chauvinists the
spokesmen for other nationalities argue that their states were established
earlier than the Russian state. For example, in 1947, the 800th anniversary of
the founding of Moscow was celebrated as symbolic of the establishment of a
centralized Russian state.[45] Before Stalin
had been laid in his final resting place, the Georgian Union Republic had begun
to celebrate the 1,500th anniversary of its capital Tbilisi.[46] Several years
later, in 1968, Armenia commemorated the 2,750 anniversary of the establishment
of its capital Erevan,[47] and at the
beginning of the 1970s Uzbekistan celebrated the 2500th anniversary of the
city of Samarkand.[48]
The Presentation of a Region in the
Mathematical Models of the Soviet Economy: Political Aspects
An
economic system may be described by a variety of methods, including a scalar
optimization model and an equilibrium model.[49] The
equilibrium model emphasizes the existence of a set of participants, each of
whom aspires to increase the value of his objective function on the basis of
the principle of Pareto optimality. One could say that the participants in an
economic system are its regions. Let us denote a region as r, such that
r=1,...,R. The objective function of the region fr(x)r
could be given on the set of the final goods that are consumed by the participants:
the vector of these products is denoted by xr/=xr{xr1,...,xrn}.
Every region has its own limits on the production of final goods. Let us denote
the vector of these goods by yr=yr{yr1,...,yrn} and the set of the constraints by Qr
where yrÎQr.
One could assume that each participant realizes his output by using prices. Let
us denote the vector of prices p where p={p1,...,pn}. The
revenue of the region, pyr is a budgeting constraint on the purchase
of commodities of the sum pxr, pxr£pyr.
Naturally the total consumption of goods in the system x=Sxr could not exceed their production y=Syr
, where x£y.
This
model also assumes the usage of a very important principle of the distribution
of income among the participants. In accordance with this principle, the income
of a region belongs to that region. Meanwhile because the region is a part of a
larger economic system which has expenses for the production of public goods or
for the redistribution of income to achieve certain social goals, it is
necessary to redistribute the income in the system. If Lr is the
coefficient of the redistribution of income of a certain region, then the final
income of a region will be Lr(pyr). The coefficient Lr
could be more or less than 1. It is only important that S Lr(pyr)= Spyr.
The problem of redistribution of income in a system is external to the economic
system and is determined by the social organization of the society.
As
a whole, the model of equilibrium which also involves redistribution of income
could be expressed in the following manner (the state could be one of the
participants of the system):
Model
1: fr(x)rfi extr.
yrÎQr
pxr£ Lr(pyr) S Lr(pyr)= Spyr
x£ y
Another
method of describing an economic system is based upon the introduction of a
global criterion of optimality for the whole system. This criterion could be
formed on the basis of the same set of final goods as the objective functions
of the regions. Let us denote this criterion F(x). The set of constraints could
be noted by Q/Q»Qr.
As a whole this model would be expressed in the following manner
Model
2: F (x)Þ extr.
xÎQ.
These
two methods of describing an economic system under certain conditions are
convertible, as has been demonstrated by Abraham Bergson[50] and Gerard
Debreu[51]. The model of
equilibrium under very natural conditions when px=pyr (that is, when the income of the
participants is completely used; this assumes that the objective function fr(x)r
is not saturated for at least one product) can be converted into a scalar
optimization model of the following form:
Model
3: F(x) = F [( fr(x)rmr] Þ
extr.
yÎQ
x£ y
where mr corresponds
to the weight of the participants. This weight is determined by the income that
the participant receives and the nature of his objective function.
Traditionally,
the models of equilibrium and scalar optimization were used to describe
different economic systems, distinguishable on the basis of the class of
mechanisms that they use in their performance. The equilibrium model has been
used to describe market economies while, the description of planning systems,
models of scalar optimization have been used. Enrico Barone, Fred Taylor, Oscar
Lange, and Abba Lerner undermined this approach to the description of a
planning system by demonstrating that prices and money could be used in both
market and planning systems. The discovery that it was possible to convert one
method of describing of an economic system into another finally established
the independence of a method of describing of a system from the class of
mechanisms used in the performance of the system. This provides a basis for the
separation of the method of describing a system from ideological
considerations. Meanwhile, the above mentioned method of describing an economic
system became very important for the planning system itself. The point is that
by using the scalar optimization method to describe a system without making
clear the weights of the participants (see Model 2), it is possible to disguise
the problem of the distribution of income among the participants, in this
particular case, among the union republics. Practically speaking, in describing
an economic system by means of Model 3, we also assume a certain method of
distributing income. This means that we assume that the weights of all
participants are equal. This equality in turn assumes as a rule that all of the
resources of the participants belong to the whole system.[52] When the
economic system is described by an equilibrium model (Model 1), the extent to
which a region's income belongs to the
region becomes clear. From this standpoint, two different points of view have
emerged among the Soviet economists who are involved in mathematical modelling
of the Soviet economic system. The pioneers in the area of the application of
mathematical methods to optimize the allocation of resources[53] used only the
models of scalar optimization, both ideologically and heuristically since they
regarded these as the most appropriate for a planning system. Since that time, certain Soviet scholars
have continued to develop this point of view. On the basis of my experience in
communication with Soviet economists, I would argue that, at the present time,
the typical political orientation of these scholars lies in the direction of
supporting autocratic regimes, and that they are less liberal people.[54] At the same
time, in the Soviet Union other scholars developed a description of the Soviet
economy, based upon equilibrium models, certain of which emphasized the spatial
aspect of the problem, designating as a region either a large part of the
Soviet territory (west or east)[55] or a union
republic[56] In unofficial
discussions among Soviet economists, attention was paid to the fact that
territorial distribution may be based upon the assumption that resources
located in a given region belong to all of the given population or society.
This assumption is less painfully received by the population of a country with
a homogeneous national attitude (China,
for example) or where diverse nationalities have intermingled (the United
States, for example).
In
countries where there are many nationalities, and they are territorially
isolated, the redistribution of income among the separate territories invokes
quite a painful reaction from the population of regions that have better
resources. One reason for the appearance of a centrifugal force in
multinational empires is that the population of a given territory feels that it
is being exploited by the center, which takes for itself the income from the
resources of that area.
What
sort of relations should there be between the center and such national
structures? In principal, the unification of nations may be based upon several
of a variety of principles, such as those upon which are built such diverse
organizational types as the British Commonwealth of Nations, the Common Market,
and the Council for Mutual Economic Aid; here one finds a rich spectrum of
relations.
I
will note that relations between the U.S.S.R. and East European, socialistic
countries within the limits of COMECON are based upon the principle that each
country receives an adequate income from the resources at its disposal. A very
real question then arises: Why should the relations between the socialistic
republics within the boundaries of the U.S.S.R. be built on the principle of
redistribution of income between the republics?
In
any case, the using the equilibrium
models which involves participants
represented by the union republics, could result in the growth of nationalism
in those areas. In the model it is made explicit that the government withdraws
a part of their income from the union republics, and this creates the
impression that Russians exploit other union republics. The paradox of the
situation lies in the fact that the standard of living in the union republics
(with the possible exception of White Russia) is noticeably higher than in
Russia (RSFSR).[57] Moreover, the
standard of living of the native peoples in many union republics, particularly
in the Caucasus and Central Asia, is higher than that of the Russians who live
in these areas. This is a result of the fact that the major sources of high
income for the native peoples are the sale of fresh fruits and vegetables, and
the participation in the secondary economy. As was mentioned previously, the
greater part of the Russian population in the union republics is involved in
heavy industry and works in large enterprises.
The
fact that the Russian population has a lower standard of living than other
nationalities is a source of some concern to the nation's leaders. The central
government in recent years has taken steps to help equalize the living
conditions of people in RSFSR and in other union republics. On the one hand,
the Soviet government announced programs for the non-black earth zones of
central Russia.[58] On the other
hand, in recent years the central government has taken energetic steps to
control the level of living conditions in several union republics, most
noticeably in Georgia, by introducing severe restrictions on the exportation
of fruit and strict penalties for participation in the secondary economy.
Certainly
the higher level of living conditions in the union republics compared to the
RSFSR does not preclude the possibility that were these republics to be
independent from Russia, the people in these republics would attain an even
higher standard of living. However, the problem of the extent to which Russia
exploits other union republics is quite complicated and outside of the scope of
this presentation. Without minimizing the importance of the economic factor in
the nationalist movements in the union republics, I would argue that the
centrifugal forces are to a great extent motivated by the desire of the union
republics to be separated for political reasons; freedom is an independent
good. Of course, certain social groups base their desire for independence on
other considerations. For example, some leaders of the Central Asian republics
could complain that they can be leaders of Soviet delegations only to second
and third-ranked countries, whereas the leaders of a neighboring country would
be greeted in the main Western countries as the heads of independent countries.
The Double Hierarchy of the Soviet Governing System
The
Soviet system is governed by two hierarchies: ministerial and party. Union
ministries manage those factories that have significance for the entire Soviet
Union. These ministries are subordinate to the Council of Ministers of the
Soviet Union and are located in Moscow. If an enterprise is significant only
for a union republic, it will be managed by a ministry that is located in that
republic and subordinated to the republic Council of Ministers. There are, in
addition, ministries that are located in Moscow and are regarded as union-republic
ministries. This means that in certain cases the republic ministers are
subordinate both to the ministers in Moscow and to their local Council of
Ministers. The interrelations between the ministries located in Moscow and
those in the union-republics are chaotic. Art, rather than science, reigns
here. There are now laws regulating the relations between the union ministers
and the republics. In the legal codes, very little is said about relations
between the republic Council of Ministers and the corresponding union-republic
ministers. As a result, for example, out of twenty-eight Ukrainian
union-republic ministries in 1971, nineteen had individual charters, while the
rest operated without any legal document. Due to the absence of sufficiently developed
legislation, relations between the union-republic ministries and the republic
Council of Ministers are unequal. In general, it appears that the powers of
U.S.S.R. union-republic ministries are greater in heavy industry than in light
industry[59].
Naturally,
to order the relations between the center and a republic is not an easy task.
On the one hand, conflicting technological and territorial factors must both be
taken into account in the attempt to solve managerial problems; however, on the
other hand, there exists the problem of the appropriate division of political
power between the center and a republic, and the socioeconomic relations
between the two.
In
order to understand the mechanism of economic control in the U.S.S.R., and, in
particular, the structure of relations between the republics and the central
power, one must take into account the role of the party apparatus. Bearing in
mind that factories that have significance for the Soviet Union as a whole are
not subordinated to the ministries located in the union republics, one can
imagine very complicated problems arising in the interrelations between all of
the enterprises located in any one region. If only the ministerial hierarchy
existed, the problems of interrelations between the enterprises subordinate to
different ministries but in the same region could be solved through the
apparatus of the Council of Ministers of the U.S.S.R. But at this point the
second hierarchy, which is territorially organized, enters the picture with an
impact on all participants. It is well known that the party plays a great role
in the Soviet Union, regulating virtually all aspects of the society's life.
In
certain respects, the party duplicates the activities of the ministries (for
example, managerial appointments). However, it needs to be pointed out that in
the absence of certain economic bodies, the party apparatus fulfills very
important economic functions including the coordination of enterprises located
in a given region and not subordinate to different ministries. The
interrelationships between the arty apparatus, the managers of enterprises, and
the ministries are quite complicated. Party organs are responsible for the
fulfillment of plans by all enterprises within a given republic regardless of
their departmental subordination. In this sense, the party organizations are
allies with the enterprises found in their territory in their desire to receive
a smaller plan from the center. Along with the party organs, responsibility for
the fulfillment of the republic plan, the party obliges the enterprises to
produce commodities that they would not produce under other circumstances, but
that are needed for other undertakings of the republic. Specifically, this
relates to the industrial enterprises, which are obliged by the local party
organ to produce spare parts for agriculture, to send workers, and drivers to
the harvest, and so on. These jobs are not taken into account in the plans for
industrial enterprises. Because the managers, even of a union factory located in
the territory of the republic, are both appointed and fired with the assent of
local party organs, they naturally prefer not to argue with the party, and they
agree to fulfill the party requirements. Moreover, a manager must often appeal
to the party apparatus for help in solving current problems. For example, let
us assume that a worker who is valuable to his factory commits a crime and is
arrested by the police. If the crime is minor (for example, stealing from the
factory, hooliganism, etc.) the manager may ask the party leader of the region
to order the police or the judge to releases the worker.[60]
Thus,
we see fundamental inconsistencies in the Soviet mechanism for the management
of a region. Naturally, the leaders of the country are informed about these
inconsistencies, but they look at the improvement of management mechanisms
primarily from the standpoint of their political interest in strengthening
their power. The validity of this statement becomes apparent if we keep in mind
that, on the one hand, many factors affect the political stability of the
leaders of an autocratic society in which all aspects of the life of the
society are determined by the center, and that, on the other hand, there are
absolute limits to the amount of time that the leaders can devote to the
solution of problems. They cannot work systematically more than sixteen hours
per day. Thus, one can conclude that reorganization of the management system in
the Soviet Union is, first of all, directed toward the strengthening of the leaders'
power. In certain cases, the reorganization
of work may be to the economic advantage of the system, in others to its
detriment. Let me illustrate this with an example of the reorganization of the
managerial system concerning the regions.
In
September 1953 Khrushchev was appointed first secretary of the Central
Committee of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union (CPSU). Within a few years
he managed to appoint his people to the party apparatus, primarily at the level
of provincial committee secretaries. Many of them were promised considerable
career advancement in the event of the defeat of Khrushchev's opponents. The
strength of Khrushchev's opponents lay in the economic organization. Khrushchev
then proposed the creation of the regional economic councils: Sovnarkhozy.
Through these councils, Khrushchev attempted to disperse his opponents and to
deprive them of the old economic ministerial apparatus. Upon being appointed to
the regional economic councils, not all of the executives from the old apparatus
got good new jobs. Moreover, the supervision of the economic councils passed
into the hands of the provincial (oblastnye) party apparatus. And as
already been noted, Khrushchev had his people in the regional party apparatus.
The
tremendously rapid reorganization of the ministries into Sovnarkhozy in
1957 brought many negative consequences, among them a sharp reduction in the
quality of management, complications in the organization of the Sovnarkhozy,
complications in the system of supply, and so on. For example, let us consider
the case of the ball-bearing factories. These factories, more than fifteen of
them, were subordinate to the Chief Department for Ball-Bearing Production of
the Ministry of Automobile and Tractor Industries. The apparatus of the chief department was sufficiently qualified
to elaborate a general policy for the technological development of these
factories and to help them solve their current problems, particularly if the
factory in question was new. The chief department coordinated with the buyers
the specifications of the ball-bearings that were needed. After the ministry
was disbanded, the ball-bearing factories were distributed among many Sovnarkhozy.
Each Sovnarkhozy managed only one or two ball-bearing factories and therefore was not able to
maintain a sufficient number of qualified workers to provide the same services
as the former chief department. Furthermore, the factories' rights to solve
their own problems were not affected by the organization of the Sovnarkhozy;
it should be obvious what kind of problems they experienced in the factories.
After
Khrushchev became the de facto one-man ruler, combining the duties of first
secretary of the Central Committee of the CPSU and chairman of the Council of
Ministers of the U.S.S.R., he began spending a considerable amount of time on
foreign policy (including travel outside the country) and on resolving other
general problems. He had to transfer a considerable amount of the routine party
work to Frol R. Kozlov, second
secretary of the Central Committee of the CPSU. The second secretary of the
Central Committee of the CPSU is a rather powerful figure. He decides many
routine matters and, in practice, possesses enormous power. The secretaries of
regional committees must turn to him for their daily needs and, hence, are
largely dependent on him. As shown by Stalin, who actually performed the role
of second secretary under Lenin, such a person can be the first claimant to the
post of first secretary of the Central Committee of the CPSU.
I
cannot guarantee the accuracy of what is stated below, but supposedly at a
session of the Politburo in 1962, Frol R. Kozlov (with the support of Politburo
Member Mikhail A. Suslov) demanded that Khrushchev should share power, that is,
that he should cease holding the two leading posts; he hoped to win the post of
first secretary of the Central Committee of the CPSU. The stormy Politburo
session ended with Khrushchev's victory. Kozlov was removed from the party
leadership and soon died of a stroke.
Meanwhile,
it became clear to Khrushchev that the party apparatus lay largely outside his
control. It would have been difficult to replace the many regional committee
secretaries. At this point, Khrushchev carried out this well-known
reorganization of the party apparatus and the regional economic councils. After
dividing the regional party committees into industrial and agricultural
branches, he reappointed the secretaries of the regional committees. But the
main thing he achieved was that, while he essentially retained the officials
from the old apparatus, he divided them and set them against each other. Thus,
for example, what kind of friendship could there be between secretaries of the
industrial and agricultural regional party committees, if only one of them could
be the first to greet Cuba's leader, Fidel Castro, when he visited the region?
With
regard to the regional economic councils, Khrushchev hastened to remove them
from the power of the regional committees. The number of economic councils was
sharply reduced from 105 to 45, and they became zonal. They were subordinated
to the secretaries of regional committees only as organizations situated in
their territories.
The
reorganization of the party apparatus and the system of management instituted
by Khrushchev in 1962 did not help him to maintain his power. On the one hand,
Khrushchev aspired to dictatorship, to independence from the party apparatus.
Yet, on the other hand, he was charitable enough to his enemies to merely
relieve them of their high positions, granting them instead either diplomatic
posts abroad or retirement pensions. Under these conditions, the leaders of the
Party apparatus were comparatively easily able to unite and dismiss Khrushchev.
The
Soviet leaders who succeeded Khrushchev in 1964 soon returned to the old system
of management by ministers and revived the old system of unified provincial
committees of the Communist party. Perhaps one of the main reasons for this
reorganization was the perceived need to concentrate power in the center in order
to counteract centrifugal forces. (This is especially pertinent if we keep in
mind that the new leadership was collective, that is. it had no dictator.) Very
soon, however, Brezhnev also tried to increase his power by reorganizing the
system of management. This reorganization of industry in the U.S.S.R., which
was based on the introduction of associations (ob'edineniia ) is also, evidently, largely of a
political nature. I do not want to
belittle the role of associations, which in principle may prove to be effective
organizations of decentralized management, the serious suspicion remains that
associations are also intended to destroy the old central economic apparatus
and to subordinate the management of industry to the local party apparatus. It
is enough to recall that the apparatus of ministerial chief departments (glavki),
which the associations are meant to replace, includes approximately two-thirds
of the apparatus of the ministries. We also know that the associations can be
interlocked and distributed through the entire U.S.S.R. From what has been
said, one can try to formulate a hypothesis about who among the country's
collective leadership finds this reorganization advantageous and who
resolutely resists it.
But
the fact that Brezhnev has been unable to introduce the associations into many
branches of industry demonstrates that he probably had less political power
than did his predecessors, who easily reorganized the system of management upon
their succession to power. Gorbachev
strives for a decentralized mechanism that eliminates, or at least greatly
restricts, the Party's and ministries' managerial role. The political
considerations behind Gorbachev's strategy have already been mentioned. I only
want to note once again that, besides purely substantive reasons, Gorbachev is
also driven by the desire to enhance his own power position, since his chosen
course allows him to shift the blame for economic problems onto the local
Soviets elected by the popular vote.
Alternative Solutions of the Imperial Problem
As
we have seen, the Soviet control system rests on the principle of national
administrative regions. On the one hand, this allows national cultures to
develop; on the other, it fosters separatist centrifugal forces.
The
growth of nationalism cannot fail to disturb the leaders of the U.S.S.R. who
continue the old Russian policy of strengthening and expanding the empire. This
process could be stopped by several methods. One method would be the
elimination of the union republics. Such a move could be based upon the notion
that a new nationality has appeared in the Soviet Union; regardless of their
former nationality, all people could be referred to as the Soviet people. On
the other hand, this would necessitate the reorganization of the system of management,
so that the principle regions would be the previously discussed economic
regions. These in turn would have to be provided with certain kinds of
institutions, such as, Supreme Soviets, Councils of Ministers, and Central Committees of the Communist Party.
The possibility of designating regions as the basic political units of the Soviet Union was a subject of
discussion in the 1920s, the idea having been proposed by Professor
Aleksandrov. The possibility of eliminating the union republics and substituting
economic regions on the ideological basis of a united Soviet people was again a
subject for very serious discussion in the middle of the 1970s during the
preparation of the new Soviet constitution. However, as we now know, the
traditional point of view prevailed: the Soviet Union is an empire headed by
the Russian people.
With
a sincerity unusual for his administration, Leonid Brezhnev spoke about this
dilemma at the time the draft of the new Soviet constitution was being
discussed.
Let
me address the issue of those proposals which the Constitutional Commission
regarded as essentially incorrect.
As
is well known, a new community of people has emerged in the U.S.S.R.: The
Soviet People. On this basis, several comrades,their number of course, is small
came to an improper conclusion. They proposed the introduction into the
constitution of the concept of a unified Soviet nation; either the liquidation
of union and autonomous republics or a sharp reduction in the autonomy of the
former, depriving them of their right to withdraw from the U.S.S.R. and of
their right to external relations. In the same direction, there are proposals
to eliminate the Nationalities' Council and to establish a one-chamber Supreme
Soviet. In my opinion, the incorrectness of such proposals is obvious. The
sociopolitical unity of the Soviet people in no way signifies the disappearance
of national differences. Thanks to the consistent carrying out of Lenin's
nationalities policies, we, in the process of building socialism, simultaneously,
and for the first time in history, were able to solve successfully the
nationalities' question. The friendship of the Soviet peoples is inviolable; in
the process of the construction of communism they are steadily coming closer
together to the mutual enrichment of their spiritual lives. But we would be
setting out on a dangerous course if we were artificially to force that
objective process of the rapprochement of nations. Lenin insistently warned
against this, and we will not deviate from his precepts."[61]
It was not by accident that the first line of
the previous anthem was preserved in the text of the new national anthem of the
Soviet Union, which was accepted at the same time as the new constitution:
"Unbreakable union of freeform republics/Great Russia has welded forever
to stand."
The
available evidence indicates that Gorbachev is also disinclined to use the idea
of a Soviet people to try and integrate the empire. He will either opt for a
federation, with separate national regions enjoying much greater rights, or,
should the centrifugal forces get out of hand, revert to a much more rigid
system headed by the Great Russian people.
Notes and
References
7
Russophilism
The current
trepidations experienced by the Soviet empire and the future of the empire boil
down to the problem of nationalism, both Russian and regional. This part of the
book is devoted to russophilism, which is really the principal issue.
The prominent
Soviet historian and publicist Alexander Yanov can rightfully be considered a
pioneer in this area. As early as 1968,
when almost nobody else understood the impending danger of russophilism, Yanov
opened the discussion on slavophilism with his article "The Mystery of Slavophile
Criticism," published in Literary Issues.[62]
After tracing how the slavophile movement
historically evolved from liberalism to chauvinism, Yanov also calls attention
to the new slavophiles.
In his book on
the Russian right-wing movement published in the late 1970s[63] and in particular in his new book on
this topic[64], Yanov examines the ideological tenets
of the russophiles in detail and from a long historical perspective.
Some of
Yanov's ideas are open to criticism: in
many ways I share the views of those who cannot accept his practical proposals
concerning the conduct of Soviet-American relations and am of the opinion that
Yanov oversimplifies the question of how the West should relate to Soviet
readers in general and to liberal readers in particular. However, in my opinion, these disagreements
with Yanov should not be allowed to obscure the central theme of his work, his
innovative approach to understanding of
danger of russophilism. The very fact
that in Western literature this question has not been given its due
consideration makes it all the more fitting for us to pay particular attention
to Yanov's works.[65]
I do not mean to imply by this that the russophiles will necessarily
triumph, but, it seems, that to discount the role of the russophiles, to
dismiss them as an insignificant phenomenon, would be a dangerous oversight.
Local
nationalisms, in my view, are the direct result and consequence of Russian
nationalism and express the local aspirations to be independent from Russia.
And, finally,
I will pay particular attention to the question of anti-Semitism insofar as it
represents another very peculiar side of russophilism. All forms of nationalism seek their
antipodes. In different countries
various ethnic groups are singled out for this purpose, groups that are
generally felt to be standing in the way of the development of the national
spirit. The russophiles by virtue of
historical peculiarities have chosen the Jews. The Jewish problem in the
U.S.S.R. is further aggravated by the fact that Soviet Jews lack any
territorial base in the country (the same is true, though, for some other
ethnic groups, for exampe, the Germans), but unlike these other territorially
deprived nationalities, the Jews do (did in the past and will probably in the future) have an important
influence on the development of the country.
Patriotism, Nationalism and Chauvinism
I have heard
it said many times that nationalistic tendencies in Russia will be the
salvation of the country. Just like other nations, the Russian nation has a
right to its own self-identity and its own indigenous course of development.
Moreover, insofar as it is in Russia's own self-interest to liberalize and to
keep in step with the developed democratic powers, a renewed Russia, after
throwing off the shackles of communist doctrine, will gradually adopt that
course. And it is precisely those Russian nationalists who are true believers
who will take the country down that path. Thus, in the Soviet political
strategy, room is made for a combination of moderate Russian nationalism,
liberalism, and a disposition towards peace.[66]
Before
embarking upon this topic, I feel a few definitions are in order. Love toward
one's nation ranges over a broad spectrum characterized by the following rough
subdivisions. One extreme exhibits a radical phase which could be called cosmopolitan,
that is, an individual regards himself as the citizen of the universe and
refusies to acknowledge belonging to any one particular nationality. At the
opposite pole is the chauvinistic band of the spectrum, this is, a person
considers his nation as being not only superior to all others, but believes his
nation must rule over all other peoples and people who violate the harmony of
this arrangement must be expelled by whatever means, including extermination.
Between these
two extremes there are at least three intermediate phases. Starting from the
cosmopolitan pole, we can pinpoint the next group the internationalist
group. An internationalist is a person who combines love for his own country
with equal affection for other countries. The next group can be designated as patriotic. Here, a person asserts, and proudly so, his
attachment to a particular nation. But he believes that his people are no
better and no worse than the others, merely different. The fact that other
people belong to other nationalities and are proud of it is just as reasonable
as his own pride in his group.
Next comes the
nationalistic phase. Unlike a patriotic state of mind, a nationalist
holds that the nation to which he belongs is the best one. Still, he feels no
animosity toward other peoples and does to not wish to subordinate them.[67]
Nationalism of
the last kind branches into two
subclasses. The first emphasizes the distinctness of a given group, its
profound difference from other nations. This outlook is characteristic of
Russian ruralists (pochvenniks). Their anti-Western sentiments are
rooted in their belief that the Russian system of values, with its emphasis
upon collectivism and spirituality is
completely opposite to Western values based upon individualism and mercantilism.
The other mode
of nationalism is based on the idea of a particular nation evolving in the same
way as many other developed nations but managing to achieve better results
along the same path. This type of nationalism will be considered in greater detail
when I discuss Academician Dmitrij Likhachov. At this point, I only want to
note that this outlook is rather moderate and tends to gravitate strongly
toward patriotism.
I have no
doubts whatsoever that in the Soviet Union there is an appreciable number of
such liberally inclined patriots and even moderate nationalists. Proceeding
from the general view that the preservation and development of variety is
essential to the development of any system, I am very sympathetic to the desire
on the part of a given group to preserve its unique self-identity. (At the same
time, considering the consequences that occur as a result of the division of
the world along ethnic lines, I can
appreciate the merits of arguments in favor of doing away with nationalities
and creating a single human nationality.)
However, the danger does not come directly from this kind of patriots
and moderate nationalists. In a period of crisis for the empire, to the
forefront come not the moderate nationalists, but their more radical brethren:
Russian chauvinists. Moreover, the
nationalistic circles that, in principle, might align themselves with the
liberals, to a significant degree become the allies of the chauvinists insofar
as the chauvinists express the interests of the country that is very dear to
the nationalists. The nationalists sometimes find it difficult to deal with
the chauvinists' coarseness, staunchness, and lack of refinement, but they are
attracted by the chauvinists' resolve to defend the greatness of the nation.
This is precisely what happened with the Germans when Hitler came to power.
This
discussion about attitude toward one's homeland is illustrated by my dispute
with George Gibian, a professor at Cornell University. Our debate was initiated
by my article "Will Glasnost Bring the Reactionaries to Power?."[68]
Professor
Gibian kindly mentions that my article draws attention to dangerous tendencies
in the U.S.S.R.'s era of glasnost. But his appreciation seems merely polite,
for obviously he thinks that I have made some very essential errors, and he
goes on to lodge objections that, if true, would nullify my article. In
particular, he accuses me of failing to differentiate between various types of
slavophiles. In addition, he holds that I "tar everybody with the same brush
of anti-Semitic reactionism."
How shall I
answer these allegations? I believe a scholar should not rush to accuse his
opponents of making errors, but should try to understand their position and
the assumptions under which that position might be correct. Only after this
attempt has been made is it time to express disagreement with basic
assumptions.
Let me,
therefore, clarify the assumptions of my article, in order to see whether
Gibian's criticisms hold up. Gibian is completely right in saying that, historically,
Slavophiles have held many different opinions, and that I did not discuss these
differences. But the assumption of my
article was that, in addition to being many faceted, the russophile movement is
also in some way a single movement; and on that assumption, I sought to
emphasize the aspects that make it a unity. Those aspects are the special
status that russophiles accord Russia among nations; and Orthodoxy among religions, and the championing of authoritarianism
as the appropriate type of regime for Russia. Undoubtedly, the weight given to
each aspect varies from one russophile to another.
Thus, I agree
that the present Russian nationalists include different groups. As a matter of
fact, I noted this in my article: "No doubt, an appreciable number of
moderate nationalists do live in the Soviet Union, and do believe that Russia
would benefit from political liberalism." But the Soviet Union lacks
elections in which such beliefs can be transformed into power. Therefore, I
concentrated my attention on the reactionary groups of nationalists.
I did so on
the basis of two further assumptions: first, that the Soviet empire is (in
Gorbachev's words) "on the eve of a crisis," and second, that in a
period of crisis, moderate nationalists "tend to become allies of the
chauvinists, attracted as they are by the latter's ideals and resolve."
Looking at Russian nationalism not as a pollster but as a political scientist,
I expressed fear that the fanaticism and sincerity of the chauvinists would
overcome the resistance of their more moderate brethren. In a time of
emergency, the moderate Russian nationalists might well end up following the
reactionaries, even while expressing disgust at their fanaticism and
immorality.
Such are the
assumptions under which I posed the question whether glasnost might bring to
power a reactionary regime. I remain convinced that it is not an idle question.
A second
aspect of Gibian's criticism also merits a response. He says I leave out
"those in the Soviet Union who have spoken out for a generous conception
of Russianness - who reject and militate against xenophobia, anti-Semitism, and
anti-Asian prejudice, and who stress the tolerant tradition of the Russian
national heritage." He particularly cites Academician Dmitrij Likhachov as
"the most prominent and vocal advocate of such Russian patriotism."
Gibian calls my failure to mention Likhachov's generous conceptions "a
glaring error."
No doubt,
Likhachov is dedicated to Russia, and he is doing great things to develop
Russian culture, to bring together Russia and the West, to criticize Stalin's
era (when he himself was in prison), and so forth. Nevertheless, I hope that
Gibian has had the opportunity to read the long interview that Likhachov gave
to the liberal journal Ogonyek[69] concerning the millennial anniversary
of Russia's conversion to Christianity. Westerners and nonspecialists might
find this interview innocuous enough. But to readers familiar with the Russian
skill in making points by indirection, it is anything but "generous Russianism."
Let me give some examples.
"To the
extent that Christianity is international, it is a great religion," says
Likhachov. "I do not want to mention religions belonging to one folk.
There are several such religions, but it is a great deficiency of these
religions." This is someone who rejects anti-Semitism?
"The
state simply cannot live with divided beliefs," Likhachov maintains.
"This was a multinational state and that is why it required an
international religion." This is an advocate of tolerance?
"Novgorod
did nothing to unite Russia because it was a republic; the Metropolitan of the
Russian world moved to Moscow [an autocracy] ,and Moscow became the symbol of
the spiritual integration." This is an advocate of democratic rule?
Likhachov says
that from the baptism of Russia came a "synthesis with the culture of the
Byzantine empire, the most advanced country of that time." This "most
advanced country" was then ruled over by Basil II, a ruler perhaps best
noted for having put out the eyes of fifteen thousand prisoners of war.
In an article
entitled "Russia," published after the interview, Academician
Likhachov reiterates the theme of Russian superiority, but this time compared
to world culture in general.
The Russian
land created its own artistic styles during the ancient period of its evolution
prior to the era of Peter's reforms. After Peter, Russian culture became part
of the global development of art in the West constantly transforming artistic
styles arising in the West and resounding in Russia. Resounding and how! In
Russia every style assumed not only its peculiar but also its ultimate form.
[My underline. A. K.][70]
For all these
reasons, I would not count on Academician Likhachov to represent the forces of
liberalism in a time of systemic crisis.
But let us go
back to the main topic of the present section: to the history of Russian
nationalism in the Soviet period. In the context of the present work, I feel
that it is permissible to use the terms russophiles, nationalists,
and chauvinists as synonyms. I understand that there is an essential difference
between these concepts, but with respect to those historical events that I will
cite, the various aspects that define these three terms are tightly interwoven.
Meanwhile, when chauvinism can be singled out as such and when it is advisable
to do so in the context of our discussion, I will make it a point to use the
term chauvinists.
Russian Nationalism (Some
Soviet History)
The opinion
that the sharply expressed Russian nationalist tradition was interrupted by the
October Revolution and resurrected by Stalin only during the Second World War,
and then used by him in the postwar period, has gained wide acceptance.
In my view,
the nationalist tradition was never interrupted. Only its forms and its strength
changed. Lenin preserved the empire, though he justified it with communist
slogans. Under Lenin's rule the
concept of "the victory of communism in one country" as opposed to
"permanent revolution" had already begun to take shape. Translated
into laymen's terms, the first concept signified that world communism could be
achieved only under Russia's leadership;
the second meant that, for the sake of the triumph of world communism,
even Russia could be sacrificed. After Lenin's death the leading advocates of
the first point of view were Russians, Bukharin, Rykov, Tomsky, and
Uglanov; Stalin, who joined their ranks
was not a Russian, but at least was of the Russian Orthodox faith. The leading
advocates of the second point of view were Jews: Trotsky (Bronstein), Zinoviev
(Radomyslsky), and Kamenev (Rosenfeld). Of course, the first group prevailed.
By 1927, the Politburo had been swept clean of Jews; only in 1930 did Stalin
bring his protege Lazar M. Kaganovich into the Politburo.
On 12 December
1930 Stalin wrote a letter to the poet Dem'ian Bedny in which he accused him of
"slandering and defiling the Russian proletariat," of "debunking
the U.S.S.R.," and of portraying "laziness and the yearning to lie
around on the stove" as "practically a national character trait of
the Russian people in general," all at a time when "the workers of
countries throughout the world are applauding the Russian [the emphasis
is Stalin's] working class, which they recognize as their leader."
However, these were thoughts whose time had not yet come, and this letter was
published for the first time in 1952 in a 13-volume collection of Stalin's
writings[71].
But if at the
beginning of the 1930s Stalin still had reservations about praising the great
Russian people, by the middle of that decade he began praising them quite
openly.
The first
document known to me with respect to this is a 1934 letter entitled "On a
Few Mistakes in Illuminating the History of the U.S.S.R." and signed by
Stalin, Kirov, and Zhdanov. What was the point of this letter? Recall that the
Marxist historical school of Mikhail Pokrovskij, with its slogan "The
History of Russia without the Tsars," was dominant at this time. This view did not suit Stalin. The image of
the tsar had to be reintroduced.
Stalin, in fact, did reintroduce it. Here we see the glorification of
Alexander Nevsky and Peter the Great, who were constantly portrayed and
evaluated as victorious leaders.
It is curious
to note which historians Stalin elevated at this time: Victor Tarle, Sergej
Bakhrushin, Boris Grekov, and Mikhail Tikhomirov, that is, men who were neither
Marxists nor party members. They were placed at the head of Soviet historical
science in order to give a base to a return to traditional Russian ideology.
Soon
afterward, in order to be done with his right-wing confederates once and for
all, Stalin concocted the accusation against their leader, Bukharin, that he
had slandered the Russian people and demeaned the role of the great Russian
people. The height of that campaign was the declaration, in a lead article
in Pravda dated 27 January 1936, that the Great Russian people had given
the world Lomonosov, Lobachevsky, Popov, Pushkin, Chernyshevsky, Mendeleyev,
and "such giants of humanity as Lenin and Stalin." Quite a brilliant
stunt: to portray Bukharin, a Russian aristocrat by blood, as a slanderer of
the Russian people, and Stalin, a Georgian, who spoke Russian with a very heavy
accent, as the great son of the Russian nation![72]
Thus, Stalin
began propagandizing the idea of the Great Russian nation even before the
Second World War.
Nationalist
propaganda came into full bloom after the war and was signaled by Stalin's
toast to the Great Russian people at a dinner held on the occasion of the
Victory Parade on 24 June 1945. This
campaign of praising the Russian nation as an "older brother" was
accompanied by an unabashed anti-Semitism campaign under the guise of a
struggle against cosmopolitanism and against all sorts of Jewish plots,
particularly that of the Jewish doctors.
Even though
the nationalist propaganda was toned down after Stalin's death, its foundations
were nonetheless intact. The nationalist tendencies continued to develop,
particularly during the period of Brezhnev's administration.
Under Stalin
these nationalistic principles were declared openly, and in this matter it was
as though the entire apparatus was legally shifted into nationalistic
activity; in the years that followed,
on the other hand, the nationalists had to search for new organizational forms
of legal activity. Such legal slogans
and organizations were indeed found.[73]
In the
Brezhnev period Russian nationalists hid behind the slogan "Preserve the
Treasures of Russia's Past." What can one say? A concern for the treasures
of Russian culture certainly deserves everyone's respect and appreciation. The
fact that the bureaucratic system did not appropriate sufficient funds for the
preservation of these treasures, and that as a result they fell into ruin, is
not something dreamed up the Russian nationalists. The question is, what was behind this campaign?
Is it not that the All-Russian Society for the Preservation of Historical and
CulturAl Treasures with its staff in a church on Kalininsky Prospect, had
turned into one of the active nationalistic and anti-Semitic organizations?
When Andropov
came to power, one of his first official acts was to streamline this
organization. A lengthy article appeared in Izvestia analyzing the
financial problems of the All Russian Society for the Preservation of
Historical and Cultural Treasures. Several articles on Russian nationalism
also appeared in Pravda.
Specifically, Pravda published a story by the renowned author of
detective novels, Iulian Semyenov, in which, under the guise of a conversation
between a Soviet intelligence officer and members of the Gestapo, nationalism
and anti-Semitism are condemned.[74] There was also a humoresque, which, in
a brilliantly witty style, poked fun at monuments to Russia's pseudo-heroes.[75] This is all testimony to Andropov's
antinationalistic policies.
In saying
this, I in no way wish to whitewash Andropov. His antinationalistic course was
accompanied, first of all, by unabashed militaristic and anti-American
propaganda, including such steps as the destruction of a Korean airliner. This
is evidence once again of how opposite tendencies can be meshed together in a
bizarre fashion, that is, how one can carry out a course of expansionism by
declaring the unification of various nations into one multinational empire with
a large and growing proportion of people who are not of the native nationality.
However, this sort of decisive action on Andropov's part demonstrates that
significant anti-russophile forces exist in the country even today.
However, all
of Andropov's antinationalistic measures have not served in any serious way to
diminish feelings of nationalism among the people.
Russian Nationalism in Its Present Stage
Outwardly,
Gorbachev does not seem to encourage nationalism. However, it is under his rule
that a campaign has begun from above to replace personnel, a campaign
that Egor Ligachev, at that time the second secretary of the Central Committee
of the CPSU, has called a policy of "the regional replacement of
personnel." This means that in the republics the control of Russian
personnel will be tightened and that advancement will be given first of all to
those representatives of local nationalities who have studied and received
training in Russian regions (or, at the very least in Slavic Regions).
Rather sharply
expressed russophile tendencies have begun to receive greater coverage in the
press. Especially zealous are such russophile journals as Molodaia Gvardia,
Nash Sovremennik, and Moskva.
It seems that Novyj Mir assumed a peculiar nationalistic stand
(but far from chauvinistic) geared toward creative intelligentsia, that is,
toward presenting profound criticism of the existing socio-economic system and
communist ideology, professing a religious orthodox Christian renaissance, and so forth.
The battle
against alcoholism is one of the main campaigns for "clearing the
air" begun by Gorbachev.[76]
Without a doubt, drinking has become a serious impediment to Russia's
further development. The russophiles did not fail to immediately take advantage
of the situation in order to find the legal means with which to develop
nationalistic propaganda. To this aim they use the new, mass-circulation
journal Sobriety and Culture. The basic position taken by the journal is
that there has been no tradition of alcohol consumption in Russia: this was
invented by the enemies of the Russian people. In Russia there was a tradition
of drinking tea! And the journal is full of praise for this particular
beverage: it recommends various ways to brew it, it includes photographs of
people dressed in traditional Russian clothing seated around a samovar, and so
on. To complete the nationalistic
picture, the journal printed an article exposing a country in which the
problems of alcoholism and drug abuse truly are growing. The reader might
expect that this country would be, if not Sweden or Finland, then at the very
least that bulwark of imperialism, the United States. But alas, in strict
keeping with the nationalistic standard, a rising tide of alcoholism, as it
turns out, is characteristic of Israel! In V. Demin's lengthy article on the upsurge
of alcoholism and drug abuse in Israel entitled "The Logic of Violence-The
Logic of Degradation," a theoretical basis is provided for this
phenomenon.[77] It goes something like this: What can
you expect from Zionists-Fascists-Imperialists who destroy innocent people? How
else can they react to their evil deeds
than by increasing their consumption of alcohol and narcotics?
The position
of major newspapers, especially the "first of the first" newspaper Pravda,
is rather ambiguous. In this respect, an article in Pravda that stands
out by virtue of its frankness is that of Oleg N. Trubachev, a corresponding
member of the Soviet Academy of Sciences[78]. This article details quite openly and
frankly, as is only proper during a period of glasnost, the "more than modest
position of the Russians" and the "demeaning of the independent
historical past of the Slavs" in the works of certain Western
historians. Without any semblance of
verbal equivocation, Trubachev writes about the grandeur of the Russian
language compared to the languages of the other nationalities that comprise the
U.S.S.R. Finally, Trubachev's article contains a panegyric directed towards
Aleksandr S. Pushkin's famous poem "To the Slanderers of Russia."
This poem, which praises Russia's role as a hangman, was written by Pushkin in
1831 immediately after the suppression of the Polish uprising by Nicholas I.[79]
On 21
August 1988, Pravda devoted an
entire page to an article by Vera Tkachenko entitled "The Motherland Was
Given to Us One Time Only, and to Our Death"; in the middle of the article
looms a photograph of rural Russia, with birch trees - the symbol of Russia.
During Stalin's time, an article bearing this title would have appealed to
Soviet citizens to love Russia because it is the best country on earth with the
most progressive political system: socialism. This article preaches suffering, mysticism, and irrational
nationalism. It calls for a Russian to be proud of being able to share the
hardships with his country, to be buried in his motherland. Public reaction to
this article was published by Pravda on the 7 September 1987. In spite
of some critical reviews, the great majority of responses to Tkachenko's
article were positive.
An eruption of
nationalism took place on 13 March 1988 with the publication in Sovetskaia
Rossiia of an article, taking up an entire page, that sadly enough, became
widely known as a letter by Nina Andreeva. This article was actually a
manifesto of Russian national-socialism.
I also want to
mention the appearance of a russophile newspaper, Literaturnyj Irkutsk.
While it is not a major newspaper, its repute extends beyond its local region,
if only because it is headed by a well-known Russian russophile writer named
Valentin Rasputin.
But the main
thing that I wanted to focus on here is the new, spontaneous phenomena,
occurring from below in the Russian nationalist movement, which have developed
during the period of glasnost.
The old
movement for the preservation of historical treasures has grown even stronger
and taken on even sharper forms.[80] From all indications, the All-Russian
Society for the Preservation of Historical and Cultural Treasures has turned
into a bureaucratic organization. In the early 1980s, for some reason, at the
Ministry of Aviation Industry a new organization, Pamiat, was created as a
society for history and literature buffs, but the program of this organization
is essentially the same as that of the All-Russian Society for the Preservation
of Historical Treasures. Whereas at the head of the previous society stood such
luminaries as the hero of Stalingrad, Marshall V. I . Chujkov, and the extremely
talented writer V. Soloukhin, at the head of Pamiat we find such people as the
hysterical photojournalist Dmitry D. Vasil'ev, whom nobody knows, and the psychologically
imbalanced doctor of economic sciences Valery N. Emelyanov, (who brutally
murdered his wife and was acquitted after doctors declared him mentally ill),
the author of a book published in Paris under the title Dezionization.[81] Pamiat operates not only in Moscow, but
in other cities as well, including Leningrad and Sverdlovsk.[82]
In Moscow this society organized its meetings, in which huge numbers of
people participated, in the halls of the club of the "Dynamo"
factory, the Gorbunov club, and so forth. They accompany their activities
related to the preservation of historical treasures and the environment with
unabashed anti-Semitic propaganda. The book Protocols of the Zionist Wisemen
is the bible of this society. Excerpts are read from it at its heavily attended
meetings.
On 6 May 1987,
four hundred members of the society organized a demonstration near the Kremlin
and demanded a meeting with Gorbachev and Boris N. Eltsyn, a candidate to the
Politburo and a secretary of the Moscow branch of the party. Eltsyn agreed to a
meeting and the demonstrators, escorted by militiamen, marched down Gorki
Street to the headquarters of the Moscow Soviet. On 3 June 1987, Izvestia
wrote that the members of Pamiat who took part in the meeting came away quite
pleased with it. On 17 May 1987, the liberal newspaper Moscow News
published an article about this meeting entitled "Let's Talk as
Equals." Let us take Mr. Eltsyn's word when he said in June 1989 that he
considers his meeting with Pamiat to be a spot upon his biography.
A number of
newspapers have come out against Pamiat. Among them: Izvestia, with an
article published on 3 June 1987 entitled "Where Pamiat Leads;" Komsomol'skaia
Pravda, with an article entitled "In a State of Poor Memory"
published on 22 May 1987, Soviet Culture, with an article entitled
"On True Values and False Enemies" published on 18 June 1987, the
magazine Ogonek, no. 21, (1987), in an article "What Are You Making
a Fuss Over?" and others.
In spite of
some clamor in the press, which has diminished in recent years, Pamiat actively
pursues its course. It is especially active in Leningrad, where in 1988 they
have organized numerous meetings in Rumanzev Gardens attracting large crowds;
the authorities did not interfere.
In the last 2
years, a rift has developed in Pamiat, caused not so much by the ideological
platform but by the choice of means in the struggle for power. One group which
split from Pamiat is headed by an artist,
Igor S. Sychev. I do not know the what the attitude of the so-called
Informal Russian Cultural Fund is toward Pamiat, but its platform is basically
the same. In the winter of 1989, this fund organized a series of concerts of
Russian choral music that took place at the
Krylia Sovetov stadium in Moscow. Metropolitan Uvenal came to bless the
three thousand people who attended one such concert - this is probably the
first official blessing of such a large crowd since the Revolution. Not bad in
themselves, these concerts are accompanied by russophile propaganda. For
instance, the deputy editor of the journal Molodaia Gvardia, Viacheslav
Gorbachev, made a speech at one such concert and spoke to the audience about
the predominance of Jews in the native art and sciences.
During the
time of Gorbachev's rule a pro-Western orientation among the country's
youth in the area of art and culture has been stirred up. This orientation
is manifesting itself in the emergence of hippies, punkers, modern jazz music
and so on. At the same time
anti-Western movements among the youth have also risen sharply. These movements
were linked in the beginning to the Liubers, young people from the town
Liubertsy located outside of Moscow.[83] These were young guys who were in very
good physical shape, who were into bodybuilding, and who were trained in karate
techniques as well. They even have their own trademark form of dress:
lightweight jackets, often not in keeping with the season, wide checkered
pants, and narrow black ties. These young men for the most part did not use
drugs. Every evening they came into Moscow and chased hippies, punkers, and
heavy metal devotees, often beating them up and stealing their fashionable
clothes and jewelry.
Perhaps the
following couplet from the Liubers' anthem confirms their superpower
nationalist character:
We were born
and raised in Liubertsy,
The center
of raw physical force.
And we believe that our dream
will come true.
Liubertsy will become the center of Russia.
Who was behind
these Liubers, who was orchestrating their activities so well? How were they
able, given the conditions of Soviet life, to find the resources for sports
halls, trainers, and so on? These questions remain unanswered.
Liubers left
the scene rather quickly: perhaps they were mobilized into the army and send to
Afghanistan. According to reports in the Russian weekly Nedelya Liubers
made excellent soldiers.
But a holy
place is never empty. Soldiers coming home from Afghanistan replenish the ranks
of "Afghan Veterans" rather conservative people. Special troops
trained to disband street demonstrations were recruited from this group.
Moreover, in Moscow, and even more so in Leningrad, there formed fascist groups
made up of youth who worship the cult of Hitler.
Finally, in
discussing the development of russophilism at the present time, one cannot
ignore what is happening in Russian Orthodox Christianity. I in no way mean to
suggest that Christianity is closely linked to authoritarianism; the development of Christianity in liberal
Russia is entirely possible.[84]
But, alas, Christian ideas in Russia, to a great degree due to the fact
that they are presented by the Orthodox rite, can be exploited for the
establishment of a nationalistic ideology: Russia and Orthodoxy merge into one,
since Russia is the only large country representing Orthodoxy.
It is well
known that from the middle of the 1930s and particularly during the Second
World War and after it, Stalin did a great deal for the reestablishment of the
Russian Orthodox church. I cannot vouch for the accuracy of the data, but I
recall the following figures: in 1939 there were five hundred churches in the
U.S.S.R.; in 1953 there were eleven thousand.
After Stalin's
death, the Orthodox church would not give up its ground and began gaining more
and more momentum, especially in the 1970s when disillusionment with atheistic
ideologies grew. Under Gorbachev, religious movements, and most of all
Orthodoxy, are gaining strength. This is evidenced by a number of facts. In the
summer of 1987, the patriarch of the Greek Orthodox church, Dimitros, visited
Moscow. This was the first visit of its kind in four hundred years. Dissident
priest Gleb Iakunin, who was first relieved of his parish and then arrested,
was recently given a parish not far from Moscow. In 1986 the Moscow Seminary
admitted five times as many new students than in 1985.[85] The celebration in 1988 of the
millennial anniversary of the adoption of Christianity in Russia elicited a new
wave of religious fervor.
During his
visit to Paris in July of 1989, Gorbachev admitted that he had been baptized
and that his mother attended church.
In 1988-89,
national press published a number of articles in which a few prominent Soviet
citizens such as the mathematician and member of the Academy of Sciences Igor
R. Shafarevich (Moskovskie Novosti) and writer Iurij Nagibin,[86]
who, incidentally, hold radically different political views, openly
admitted to being religious. Delegates from among the deputies included priests
clothed in cassocks; all this received wide publicity through the television
and the press.
Roots of Russian Nationalism
Nationalistic ideas--even manifestations of
it in its most extreme forms--are nothing new to Russia.[87] Such ideas found expression even in
pre-Revolutionary Russia in the doctrine "Russia is the Third Rome and
There Shall Be No Fourth." However, in pre-Revolutionary Russia the
majority of the intelligentsia did not share this view. The intelligentsia
believed more in liberal ideas, believed that the country could achieve
greatness by following a pro-Western course. And we know, of course, that the
sympathies of a significant number of liberal-minded intellectuals lay with
the Bolsheviks.
After the
Revolution, a substantial portion of the intelligentsia came to believe that
the Bolsheviks were grooming Russia for greatness, and that the new social
system that they were creating would be the best in the world and would serve
as a model for development to the rest of the world. In this sense, the
Bolsheviks accomplished a revolution after giving legal status to the idea that
Russia would leave its provinciality and be transformed into the center of the
world. The concept of the triumph of socialism and then of communism in one
country only served to strengthen this ideology.
Some Russian
intellectuals supported the Bolsheviks because they were continuing the great
traditions of Russia by strengthening and expanding the empire. These
intellectuals quite reasonably felt that the communist slogans that the
Bolsheviks used in their noble task were merely temporary: slogans come and go,
but the empire is forever. The successes of Russia in the area of industrialization,
the victory over fascist Germany, Stalin's creation after the war of a gigantic
war machine, --all of these facts served to strengthen their belief that Russia
was the best country on earth.
Thus,
over the course of the seventy years since the Revolution several
generations, for various reasons, have believed that Russia is the best country
on earth.
Even the
liberal, pro-Western Russian intellectuals felt that Russia could outstrip the
West, using the West's own methods. The last Soviet leader who tried to use
this idea was Nikita Khrushchev. He wanted to build communism in the U.S.S.R.
as the best system in the world. He apparently still believed that, in the
contesst between the two systems, socialism be the victor.
After
Khrushchev's removal from office, the new leaders demonstrated a respectable
realism and immediately set out to forget about the utopian, propagandistic
program of building communism. The slogans about the competition between the
two systems were mothballed. I would like to point out in passing that the
Scientific Council on the Competition between the Two Systems of the Soviet
Academy of Sciences, created under Khrushchev, was disbanded.
Soviet leaders
of the post-Khrushchev period no longer claimed to be better than the West.
The new Soviet
leadership does still sometimes permit itself a few statements about the
superiority of socialism over capitalism. Gorbachev, for instance, told Margaret
Thatcher: "The socialist system has many times and in many ways
demonstrated its superiority over capitalism. This is not boasting, it's just
hard fact. And many of the possibilities of the system have yet to be unveiled
and put to use."[88]
These same views
were expressed in even starker terms by the secretary of the Central Committee
of the CPSU, Alexander Iakovlev, in an interview that he gave to Natan Gardels
for the quarterly journal New Perspectives. Iakovlev, giving very high
marks to the advantages of the socialist system, stated bluntly: "We must
again surprise you people in the West. And that time is just around corner. We
will surprise you."
I share Flora
Lewis's view that in these statements by Soviet leaders one can find a certain
wounded pride. They continue to clutch at the belief that the present system
has enough potential to make them worthy rivals of the Western powers and to
preserve the empire's prestige, but it is not very likely that they still
believe in the superiority of socialism over capitalism.
It seems to me
that at the present time, when we already have considerable experience with the
building of socialism not only in the Soviet Union, but also in China and
Eastern Europe, very few members of the Soviet intelligentsia believe in the
superiority of socialism over capitalism.
In the 1960s a considerable number of intellectuals, who had been raised
to believe in the superiority of socialism, wanted this idea to be put into
practice and wanted the Soviet Union to truly become a free, prosperous country
and a great world power. For a long time they linked this possibility to a
liberalization in the Western mold. However, Brezhnev's rule, which locked the
existing system in and set in motion the persecution of liberal dissidents, resulted
in their dispersal and left this intelligentsia with no belief in the
possibility of a successful, pro-Western development.[89]
Russophiles were also subjected to persecution, although to a much
lesser degree. Only a small fraction of russophiles, those who through their
actions opposed too strongly the canons of authority, experienced persecution.
A certain
portion of the Soviet intelligentsia, having despaired of seeing their country
achieve greatness by following a pro-Western course and perhaps influenced by
the liberal politics of the new Soviet leadership, will return to their former
ideals.
However,
another portion is trying to find its former ideals in the Russia tradition.
"We are different and better than the West. Our values are better than
those of the West since they are devoid of mercantilism, individualism, and
vanity." This is what the russophiles were saying 150 years ago, and this
is what many of them are saying again now.
There is a
great deal of evidence of a growing russophile movement within the Russian
intelligentsia.[90]
I remember
that in 1978 when S. was emigrating
from the Soviet Union, he told me that one of the main factors contributing to
his decision to leave was the feeling that he was not needed there. Even among
his close Russian friends, who up until then had been pro-Western, he noticed a
strong shift towards russophilism.
In a letter
received in Israel from a prominent Soviet scholar in the U.S.S.R., dated 3
October 1986, it is stated:
This is a new
phenomenon in our lives which began soon after your departure [that is,
approximately in 1983-A. K.] and I take it very seriously. A certain indicative reorientation in the
mindset of the Russian intelligentsia has taken place. The era of "Westernizing"
and democracy, or aspirations for such, have gone completely by the wayside.
At the end of the seventies one could still see remnants of this era, but now
the dominant trend in the mindset of our colleagues and compatriots is Russian
patriotism, ethnic awareness, etc.
Thus, the
complexity of the situation lies in the fact that russophilism is developing
under circumstances. On the one hand, among the members of the Soviet
intelligentsia, there is profound disillusionment with liberal ideas and a
disbelief both in the ideas of pedantic communism and in the idea of the possibility
of developing the country along the lines of the free Western societies: on the
other hand, there is a tradition, which has become dominant since the
Revolution, of believing that Russia is the best there is.
Notes and References
8
Some
Notes on Soviet Anti-Semitism
Historical
Comments
Throughout
Soviet history, Jews have been persecuted, though the persecution has gone on
under various banners: the struggle against Trotskyites, against cosmopolitanism,
and against Zionism. Naturally, the scale of the persecution varied over time.
Mass
Anti-Semitism goes back a long way in Russia. Here I am talking only of
anti-Semitism inspired from above. The first serious signs of anti-Semitism in
the Soviet period appeared, I think, in mid-1924. It was then that Stalin began
to move quickly against Zinoviev and Kamenev, the two other leaders who were
quite instrumental in his political survival after Lenin's death. According to
Yakubovich, it was Stalin who suggested that Kamenev be removed from the
chairmanship of the Council of People's Commissars, and replaced by Nikolai
Rykov, and ethnic Russian. Stalin argued that it was unwise in a Russian state
to have a Jew, Kamenev, head the Council of People's Commissars, or, more
precisely, to let a Jew hold the chairmanship of this post jointly with that of
Workers' and Peasants' Defense Council. These two positions, as we know, were
once jointly held by Lenin. The Politburo approved Stalin's motion. Behind the scenes,
again according to Yakubovich, Stalin allegedly told Rykov, "We shall get
rid of the Jews." And indeed, just three years later, in 1927, there was
not a single Jew left in the Politburo. Only in 1930, when Stalin brought his
own underling, Lazar Kaganovich, to the highest policy-making body, was there
again a Jew in the Politburo.
In the
following years, the repressions against the Jews intensified. Professor Boris
Moishezon told me in private conversation that in his opinion, based on the
analysis of the documents from the 1930s, the term Trotskyite was that time
associated with the Jews. I share his opinion.
An indirect
confirmation of this is the following unique fact relayed to me in the
mid-1960s by V. Kaplan. She told me that in 1937 (or in1938) her husband Kaplan
was removed from his post in Stalin's staff, where his job was to edit the
leader's works. Others of the same nationality were removed from their
positions on Stalin's staff at about the same time. Subsequently Kaplan worked
as an editor in a union publishing house, and only after Stalin's death did he
transfer to the Party Committee for the City of Moscow.
In the early
1930s the Kaplan family was very good friends with Alexander S. Shcherbakov. By
then, Shcherbakov played an important role in the party, and was appointed in
1934 as its representative to the Writers' Union of the U.S.S.R. In 1936 he
moved to Leningrad (he was appointed the second secretary of the Leningrad
Province Party Committee), and then to the Ukraine. When in Moscow on official
visits Shcherbakov would usually stay with Kaplans. During on of his visits to
Moscow from Siberia to a meeting with then-all-powerful Peoples' Commissar for
Internal Affairs, Nikolaj I. Ezhov, Shcherbakov did not stay with the Kaplans.
He called them and apologized for having to stay at the Savoi Hotel (presently
the Berlin Hotel), where he was being guarded by a man from the NKVD. He
promised to call Kaplans after the meeting. The call never came. This was a
very troubled time, and there was nothing unusual in a person not coming home
after a meeting with Ezhov. The Kaplans were understandably worried. Early in
the morning, Kaplan's wife went to the hotel. Being a close friend, she woke
Shcherbakov up and asked him why he had not called. In response, Shcherbakov
reluctantly (or, maybe only sleepily) mumbled something about his meeting with
Ezhov, who had spoken about the many Jews in the ranks of the enemies of the
people: Trotskyites. Kaplan's wife said, "How can you think that, you know
it is not true!" The subject of the conversation quickly changed. They
stayed together until 2 P.M. talking about various things, when they were
joined by Kaplan. I believe that was their last meeting.
The
anti-semitic policies of the 1930s, however, touched only the next-highest
layer of the hierarchy: The members of the Central Committee and party leaders
of the provinces (oblasty). Until 1936-38, six Jews were the secretaries
of the regional party committees in the Ukraine. After the Great Purges, there
were none. There was not, as far as I know, a single Jew besides Kaganovich,
who after 1937 held an officially elective party office of at least the level
of provincial secretary.
The Soviet
Jewish population as a whole began to feel the impact of official anti-Semitism
during World War II. This expressed itself, inter alia, in a restriction in the
admission of Jews into the best universities and colleges, in particular, into
the newly reestablished Department of International Affairs at the Moscow State
University. I personally experienced discrimination during the war, when I was
a student at the Uzbekistan Institute of National Economy in Samarkand. As the
institute did not have a graduate course, and I wished to continue my studies,
I decided to transfer in 1944 to the School of Economics at the Moscow State
University. My friends from Samarkand, who had returned to Moscow, told me by
letter that I would be unable to do this because of the restriction on the
admission of Jews to the university. Nevertheless, with great difficulty, I
obtained an interview with the dean of the School of Economics, Professor Ivan
D. Udaltsov, who questioned me on a wide variety of subjects, including whether
I had any relatives in the trade-union movement in Odessa in 1905. Needless to
say, I was refused admission. I was able to transfer, with considerable
difficulty, to the Moscow State Institute of Economics, from which I graduated
in 1946. Of the nineteen graduates of the institute, I was the only Jew
recommended for postgraduate work, although there was no shortage of Jewish
graduates whose ability was considerably greater than that of the students
recommended for such work. However, it should be pointed out that several young
Jewish men, who had graduated form the institute before the war and who had by
then returned from the front, were accepted along with me. Thus, even prior to
the creation of the State of Israel, there was noticeable anti-Semitic
discrimination in the U.S.S.R.
The official
anti-Semitic discrimination was greatly intensified in the mid-1940s in the
so-called struggle against Cosmopolitanism. The purpose of this struggle was
not only to liquidate Jewish institutions and their leaders but also to remove
Jews from management positions, from the party apparatus, and from Soviet
cultural life.
The official
anti-Jewish campaign of the late 1940s was linked with an attempt to accuse the
entire Jewish population of disloyalty to the U.S.S.R.1
It is particularly interesting to consider in addition the information received
from the well-known Soviet specialist in international finance, the late
Academician Joseph A. Trakhtenberg. According to him, sometime around February
1953, after the "Doctors' plot" had been announced and before
Stalin's death, the Editor-in-Chief of Pravda brought together a large group of
prominent Soviet Jews, of whom Trakhtenberg was one. He suggested that they
sign an appeal to the Soviet Jewish population to convince them of the
necessity of moving to Siberia. They were offered this rationalization as the
experience of the postwar years had shown, there were many Jewish renegades,
saboteur, and the like who had sold out to the Joint and other Western
intelligence organizations. According to Marxist-Leninist doctrine, the
objective cause of this phenomenon was that the Jews lacked their own working
class and collectivized peasantry. The Soviet government wished to help the
Jews to correct their mistakes and to create the appropriate conditions for
them to build their own working class and collectivized peasantry in Siberia.
Trakhtenberg told his close friends that he refused to sign the appeal.
The policies
of the Soviet government towards the Jews in the post-Stalinist period have
been fairly well described, and I do not with to dwell upon them at great
length.
What's New in Anti-Semitic Policy in the
U.S.S.R.
The main point
is that Russia's historical anti-Semitism was inherited by the U.S.S.R. With
the exception of a short period under Lenin, the anti-Semitic policy of the
Soviet government has increased. In particular, the attempt to resolve the
Jewish problem in the U.S.S.R., where, right after the Revolution, it would
seem that optimal conditions for the preservation of Judaism should exist,
ended tragically. Throughout the entire course of Soviet history, the
destruction of the Jews was carried out under the most varied of campaigns.
Anti-Semitism reached its peak at the beginning of 1953, when Stalin planned a
mass exile of Jews to Siberia. In subsequent years, though there were ebbs and surges
in anti-Semitism, it basically maintained a high level.
Before 1986,
the anti-Semitic policy was conducted directly by the Soviet government.
For many years the authorities had been orchestrating anti-Semitism from above:
officially, in the guise of combating Zionism, and unofficially, through oral
directives to various organizations. Anti-Semitism from below was tightly
controlled, and the masses were not allowed to express it in an organized
way. There were, of course, uncoordinated acts of anti-Semitism committed by
individuals that went unpunished, but they scarcely affected the larger
picture.
In the last
three years, during glasnost, the situation has changed dramatically. For the
first time in decades a number of national newspapers, for example, Izvestia,
Sovetskaya Kul'tura, and Komsomol'skaya Pravda, ran stories
condemning anti-Semitism in the Soviet Union. The word Jew with a
neutral and even positive connotations, made its appearance in the print media.
The government also took a number of steps to alleviate the situation of Jews
by sharply increasing emigration, releasing many long-time refuseniks, allowing
Jews to freely visit their friends and relatives in the West, including Israel.
Also, former Soviet Jews who have emigrated in the last twenty years are now
allowed to come back and visit. The Jewish Cultural Center opened in Moscow,
Hebrew can be taught, and Jewish theater troupes are springing up.
Whatever the
explanation is for all these changes, the changes themselves, in my view, are real.
Still, this
evidence is not sufficient to conclude that the Soviet leadership has now
wholeheartedly committed itself to eradicating anti-Semitism. There are other
facts that directly or indirectly point to the complicity of government
agencies, or at of least some very powerful individuals, in whipping up
anti-Semitism. We can at best speak only of the leadership's halfhearted
commitment to fight anti-Semitism.
First, Soviet
leaders, and Gorbachev in particular, have never publicly denounced anti-Semitism
in the country. In fact, Kanovich - a deputy to the May Congress of People's
Deputies (1989) - prepared an appeal concerning the growing anti-Semitism in
the Soviet Union. This appeal, signed by about two hundred deputies (I believe
Boris N. Yeltzin was the first to put down his signature) was handed over to
the congress Presidium directly through Gorbachev. Of the numerous appeals made
at the congress, this one was never read out (in spite of persistent reminding
to so).
Secondly, such
perfectly official magazines as Molodaia Gvardiia and Nash
Sovremennik are actively engaged in anti-Semitic propaganda variously
masked by accepted communist ideology. Some newspapers are not far behind. Of
special interest is the publication of 13 March 1988 in Sovetskaya Rossiia
of a piece that virtually amounted to a manifesto of Russian national
socialism.
Officially,
this manifesto was submitted in the form of a letter written by Nina Andreeva,
who has a teaching position at the Lensovet Leningrad Technological Institute.
From the point of view in which I am interested, I would like to draw your
attention to the following principles of the manifesto:
Another
peculiarity of the views of the "left liberals" is a blatant of
masked cosmopolitan tendency; a certain national "internationalism."
I read somewhere that after the Revolution, a delegation of merchants and
industrialists came to the Petrosovet to see Trotsky "as a Jew." They
wished to address to him their complaint regarding oppression on the part of
the Red Guard. Trotsky declared that he was "not a Jew," but an
internationalist, which highly perplexed his petitioners.
Trotsky's
understanding of "a national" was tinted with shades of inferiority
and narrow-mindedness in comparison with his idea of "an international."
He therefore emphasized "the national tradition" of October, wrote
about "the national in Lenin," affirmed that the Russian people
"have not received any kind of cultural inheritance," and things of
this sort. We are almost embarrassed to say that it was just this Russian
proletariat, whom Trotsky belittled as "backward and uncultured," who
committed, in Lenin's words, "three Russian Revolutions," and that
the Slavic peoples were in the vanguard of humanity's battle with fascism.
What I have
said is of course in no way meant to minimize the historical contribution of
other peoples and nationalities. As it is said today, it only lends support to
the body of historical truth. . . . When students ask me how it could be that
thousands of small villages in Nechernozemia and Siberia were depopulated, I
reply that this, too, is a high price to pay for Victory and the rehabilitation
of the national economy, as is the irretrievable loss of an enormous number of
monuments of Russian national culture. But I am still convince: downplaying the
significance of historical consciousness results in a pacifistic waning of
national defense and patriotic consciousness; also, the desire for the
slightest display of Great Russian national pride is written down as
chauvinism.
I am also
disturbed by militant cosmopolitanism, now associated with the practice of the
"renunciation" of socialism. Unfortunately, we are reminded of this
only when novice proponents of this movement create some kind of outrageous
disturbance in front of the Smolny or the Kremlin. And what's more, they have
gradually trained us to see in this phenomenon a kind of almost innocuous
transfer of "place of residence," and not a classoriented or
nationality change or shift; the majority of the member of this movement have
completed undergraduate and graduate education on our public funds. Overall,
many are inclined to view "renunciation" as a certain manifestation
of "democracy" and "human rights" since "stagnant
socialism" has interfered with the blossoming of individual talents. So
then, if in there in the "free world," genius and enterprise are not
valued, and haggling with one's conscience does not hold particular interest
for special agencies then we can turn back. . . .
As we know,
Marx and Engels designated entire peoples as "counterrevolutionary"
during particular periods of their histories, depending on their concrete
historical roles. I am emphasizing, not classes, not stratas, but precisely
peoples. From the basis of a class point of view, they did not hesitate to
assign vivid characteristics to a variety of peoples, including Russian, and
Poles, and also to the nationality to which they themselves belonged. It is as
if the founders of the scientific-proletarian philosophy are reminding us that
in the brotherly circle of soviet people, each people and nationality should
"preserve the honor of their youth," and not allow themselves to be
provoked into nationalistic or chauvinistic attitudes. The national pride and
worthiness of all peoples should merge into an internationalism of one
socialist society.
It is
important to note the fact that among the people named in the manifesto,
negative connotations are used exclusively in connection with those of Jewish
heritage, such as M. Shatrov, A. Rybakov, Trotsky, Iagoda, Dan, and Martov
(listed in the order in which they appear in the text).
This letter
threw the Soviet propaganda machinery into a virtual state of paralysis for
twenty-four long days. Regional newspapers, with the single possible exception
of Tambovskaia Pravda reprinted it. Various party conferences, held in
Leningrad, approved it. And only on 6 April, 1988 did an article appear in Pravda,
taking up the entire second page and severely criticizing Andreeva's manifesto.
It is hard to say why a Moscow media outlet ran Andreeva's letter, why for over
three weeks it not only went unchallenged, but was actually welcomed in many
places, why all this occurred when both Mikhail Gorbachev and Alexander
Yakovlev were away from the capital. The entire story remains shrouded in
mystery.
The important
thing, however, is not these media deviations from the general party line
against anti-Semitism, though they too merit attention. What is important is
that, in the last three year, despite official half-measures to combat
anti-Semitism, the practical responsibility for keeping anti-Semitism alive has
been delegated to the people. To this end, and organization like Pamiat
has been allowed to come into existence (even if it was not deliberately
created by the authorities, it was not banned either). Because Pamiat received
a lot of attention in the Western press, I need not dwell up it here. But
Pamiat is by no means the only unofficial society of its kind. For example, the
Independent Russian Cultural Foundation advocates similar program (see section Russian
Nationalism in Its Present Stage, chapter 7).
In recent
months, information from the U.S.S.R. includes not only all sorts of
anti-Semitic public statements by members of the group Pamiat and others like
it, but reports of anti-Semitic actions on the part of the population. Such
incidents have even been reported in the print media.
The newspaper Moscow
News, in its 29 May 1988 issue, reported an act of vandalism by two
intoxicated men, Pavel Liashchenko (fifty-four years old), and Alexander Ershov
(thirty-five years old) who defaced forty-six memorials, sixteen of which were
completely destroyed, in the Jewish section of Vostriakovsky Cemetery in
Moscow. Newspaper called the action a crime, but it also presented the vandals
as educated family men (one of them is an associate professor at the
Shakhtinsky branch of the Novocherkassky Polytechnical Institute, and and other
is a senior engineer at the same institute.) with spotless records, members of
the communist party, who committed an act of vandalism atypical of themselves.
Having gone
into a bit of detail on what happened and definitely establishing that the
defaced monuments were indeed located in the part of the cemetery reserved for
Jews, the author of the article in the paper evaluates the events thusly:
"An investigation and thorough follow-up did not reveal any evidence that
may have supported nationalistic motives on the part of the criminals. I am
firmly convinced that this was a drunken row and not an act of anti-Semitism."
The newspaper
further announces that these vandals are to be tried, and that they will
compensate for the damage caused, estimated at several thousand rubles.
It is
emphasized in the newspaper that these two thugs, who have themselves admitted
their guilt, will simply be tried as vandals. In reality, if the two were to be
tried for anti-Semitic actions, who knows what consequences might result from
this type of judicial process in such times of stagnation and growing
licentiousness of the masses?
The
development of glasnost has led to the russophiles expressing their
anti-Semitic ideas very openly, fearlessly, and sharply. In their unwashed
form, these ideas are usually expressed in the samizdat literature; for the
most part the official Soviet press still does not allow such ideas to be
published openly. Needless to say, even in earlier times the russophiles
expressed their ideas openly through samizdat. But before, this was true
primarily of russophiles who were outsides of the establishment: Shemanov,
Skurlatov, Osipov, and others. Now it is russophiles who belong to the
establishment whose ideas appear in the samizdat. I am referring to the
correspondence between State Prize laureate Victor Astaf'ev, one of Russia's
most talented contemporary writers, and renowned Soviet publicist and
researcher Natan Eidel'man, a scholar of Russian history and literature. In his
response to Eidel'man, Astaf'ev expresses his great-power views and accuses the
Jews of being responsible for many of the evil deeds perpetrated in Russia
during the post-Revolutionary period, including the brutal murder of the tsar's
family. In his response, Eidel'man tries to reason with Astaf'ev and suggest
that he look for the causes of these unfortunate occurrences in themselves, rather
than in the Jews. Another work commands attention: The book by a prominent
Soviet mathematician, a corresponding member of the Academy of Sciences of the
U.S.S.R., Igor R. Shafarevich. The work is entitled Russophobia. It
first appeared in samizdat. In 1989 it was published in the West by
Posev, and eventually it found its way into the Soviet journals (Nash
Sovremennik, in particular). The author asserts that the Jews, being
"a small nation," represent a major evil for modern day Russia. The
work lives up to the best traditions of anti-Semitic propaganda, resorting to
many old stratagems: accusing the Jews of wanting to control other peoples, for
example. The only thing lacking in the book is the accusation that Jews perform
ritual murders!
Anti-Semitism in the U.S.S.R. is currently
being fueled by yet another development. Accusations, directed against the Jews
that they had plunged Russia into the October Revolution with disastrous
results, have a long history. Considering that the highest echelon of the revolutionary
leadership (after Lenin) included many Jews (Trotsky, Zinoviev, Kamenev,
Sverdlov, Uritsky, Volodarsky) makes Jewish involvement in the October
revolution undeniable. It is quite another matter to blame the Jews for the
fact that the Russian people and other nationalities inhabiting the Russian
Empire carried out and accepted the revolution. As long as Soviet ideology
banned all doubt as to the progressive nature of the October Revolution, all
these accusations regarding the excessive role of the Jews were not pertinent.
During glasnost, official Soviet press has questioned (although rather timidly)
the expediency of the Revolution for Russia. This development makes accusations
voiced against the Jews for their participation in the Revolution more
dangerous: for now, these accusations have some official backing.
However, the
history of the Jewish people reveals that in addition to these general causes,
unabashed anti-Semitism, including pogroms, is oftentimes sparked by a current
event. For example, one the assassination of Alexander II by an organization
with some Jewish members sparked pogroms. At the present time, the burial of
the remains of the Tzar family, brutally murdered in 1918 in Ekaterinburg might
spark an anti-Semitic eruption. Allegedly, the remains of the family were
recently discovered by a Soviet journalist Riabov; this discovery was announced
in the Soviet mass media. Orthodox church wanted to have a splendorous funeral
for the remains of the innocent victims. Evidence of Jewish participation in
this operation was widely publicized. Allegedly, the person in charge of the
execution was Jacob Urovsky; he received his orders from the local authorities,
in particular, from another Jew Philip Goloshchekin, who, in turn, received his
orders from the Chief of the Central Executive Committee, Jacob Sverdlov - a
Jew.
How dangerous
life has become for Soviet Jews can be gathered from the address of N. Iukhneva
to the colloquium on the Ethnography of Petersburg-Leningrad, held on 7 June,
1988.2
Iukhneva, who
has a Ph.D. in history and who is a leading scholar at the Institute of
Ethnography of the Soviet Academy of Sciences, focused her remarks on "the
growth of aggressive nationalistic and anti-Semitic sentiments in contemporary
Russian society." She pointed to the rumors of impending Jewish pogroms
circulating in Moscow around the time of the celebration of the millennium of
Russian Christianity. Leaflets were being distributed in Moscow calling for
pogroms. (Iukhneva read the texts of two such leaflets.) Jews found letters
with threats in their mailboxes. Having citing these and a number other facts,
the speaker concluded:
Moscow is now
perched on the brink of ethnic violence. Let us hope that this won't happen.
But what we have rumors, threats, leaflets that are in and of themselves
dangerous symptoms of deep-seated problems.
Why am I
saying all this in the address devoted to Leningrad? Because the concern are
the same. Last year, in Leningrad too there was vandalism at a Jewish cemetery;
in Leningrad there are also telephone threats; in Leningrad we again have
roaming youth gangs in Mussolini-like black shirts with painted white bells.
They show up at scholarly meeting and form an appropriate backdrop to the
speeches of their leaders who sloganize about Russia for the Russians, the
purity of blood, the unmasking of Jewish-Masonic or Zionist plots. It is our
duty to do everything we can to prevent violence in Leningrad.3
In August 1989
leaflets calling for Jewish pogroms were distributed in Mosow. Direct threats
of Jewish pogroms were made in Leningrad, in Moldavia, and so on.
According to
reports from Moscow, Jews there have started, albeit sporadically, to set up
self-defense groups.
The permission
that people received under glasnost to express their views, coupled with a
much-reduced fear of doing so, has led to the resurgence of the tradition of
grass-roots anti-Semitism. Popular participation in anti-Semitic hysteria is
extremely dangerous in a period of spiritual crisis, economic stagnation,
pervasive food shortages, unusually high prices on liquor, and the future
prospects of even higher prices for consumer goods and massive layoffs of which
Gorbachev speaks quite openly.
Although
Gorbachev himself apparently regards the idea of the Great Russian people with
a certain amount of approval, there is, however, no grounds for accusing him of
anti-Semitism. One must also remember that Gorbachev, as do many other
political leaders under the conditions of a tense political struggle, tries to
maintain a centralist position between the radical liberal circles and the
nationalist socialists. The liberal program put forward by Gorbachev to
reorganize society is incompatible with anti-Semitism, and he apparently is
unwilling to give up this plan. Glasnost has given him the opportunity to
directly reject the realization of any kind of anti-Semitic actions and to
balance himself politically, shifting anti-Semitic fervor to the reactionary
circles and masses and counting their growing anti-Semitism as one of the costs
of democracy. More concretely, this means that Gorbachev's policy, in the event
of extreme necessity, may allow him to "let off steam" through the
anti-Semitic acts of the masses. This is, of course, a very risky game, since
given the current situation, the masses may themselves initiate anti-Semitic
actions, even if Gorbachev preferred not to allow this at the particular
moment. They chose the events in Nagorno Karabakh demonstrate that the
nationalistic sentiments of the masses are extremely difficult to control. In
addition, Gorbachev's rivals may even organize Jewish pogroms, which would
place him in a very difficult position both at home and abroad.
Current events
in the U.S.S.R. lead me to believe that Russia now stands on the threshold of a
new explosion of anti-Semitism.
What are the
consequences for Jewish people in the Soviet Union and for Jewish organizations
in the West? The answer is quite simple: while the situation is still
favorable, Soviet Jews should emigrate as soon as possible, without waiting for
pogrom to take place. Organizations in the West who handle Jewish emigration
from the Soviet Union face a harder dilemma. Because emigration from the
U.S.S.R. has become much easier, and because many longtime refuseniks are now
being released, it is no longer so necessary for Western Jewish organizations
to concentrate primarily on these issues, as they have quite correctly done
before. It will be recalled that Soviet authorities have also removed many
obstacles to the development of Jewish culture in the country. These phenomena
pose a challenge to Western Jews: to refocus their attention on new ways of
helping their Soviet brethren. Many Jewish leaders, taking note of the recent
positive changes, suggest that the main efforts be directed toward assisting
Soviet Jews with their cultural advancement in Russia itself. Since some
positive changes have indeed taken place, these suggestions deserve to be taken
very seriously.
Still, to base
strategy on the evidence of positive changes alone is too risky, because of the
presence of other, opposite trends, some of which I have tried to outline
above; these other trend, furthermore, appear to me to be so strong as to
require Jewish leaders to concentrate on getting as many Soviet Jews out of the
country as possible.
Even if the
Jewish organizations come to agree with my assessment of the current
contradictory situation of Soviet Jews, I am not so naive as to think that they
would immediately move to implement my suggestions in practice. There are
considerable obstacles to such a shift in policy. American Jewish organizations
have long been pressured by Israel to do everything they can to increase the
number of Soviets Jews going to Israel. That some Israeli leaders regard those
Soviet Jews who do not go to Israel as a "lost cause," strikes me as
a very narrow-minded position, when viewed from the long-term perspective of
Jewish history. Beside, Israel might experience difficulty absorbing several
hundred thousand Soviet Jews at once. And the moral side of the whole issue is
too obvious to be discussed here.
The fact that
most Soviet Jews still do not want to move to Israel naturally complicates
launching a drive for a massive emigration from the U.S.S.R.
It goes
without saying that Israel badly needs an influx of European Jews, and that
only Russia can be considered to have a serious potential in that regard. It
seems unlikely, however, that this goal can be achieved in any direct fashion.
Soviet Jews are deeply assimilated. It is quite difficult for a Jew who was not
born in Israel and does not have strong roots there, and who can live
comfortably in the Diaspora, to move to a country that is viewed as a besieged
fortress and that demands an enormous inner commitment and a strong sense of
faith in its long-term survival and prosperity. To achieve increased emigration
to Israel requires time and deep changes in the people's psychology which is
every bit as objective a constraint, as is scarcity of land and other
resources.
If the
emphasis is thus maintained on the development of the Jewish people as whole,
the present situation would seem to demand that the major efforts of Western
Jewish organizations be channeled toward rescuing Soviet Jews while it is still
possible. This does not rule out trying to strengthen Israel as the main center
of Jewish life. Considerable efforts will also be needed to establish a close
relationship between would-be Soviet emigrés and Israel, even should they
decide not to settle there.
Causes of Anti-Semitism
To gain a deeper
insight into the Jewish predicament in the Soviet Union and its possible
resolution, it seems worthwhile to examine the issue from a more general
perspective, to examine the causes of anti-Semitism and ways to respond to
them.
The causes of
anti-Semitism have been widely discussed in the literature. A nonspecialist
writing about the subject is motivated by ignorance, ambition (the latter
reflecting his faith in the nontriviality of his methodology in discussing this
age old problem), or perhaps both. As a nonspecialist, I would like to think
that my observations on the subject belong at least to second category.
It seems to me
that any social phenomenon that has persisted throughout periods of time
measured in centuries must have heterogeneous roots; that is, it must find
support in the most diverse segments of the population and have roots in a
variety of causes that may be intertwined in the most peculiar manner in each
individual group.
Indeed, if we
look at the phenomenon of anti-Semitism, we see that the most diverse groups of
people in a given country, sometimes motivated by very different reasons, have
expressed anti-Semitic sentiment. Urban and rural populations alike have been
infected with anti-Semitic spirit; educated as well as uneducated classes;
intellectuals and "people of the earth"; poor people as well as
middle and wealthy classes: persecutors and the persecuted; slaves and free
citizens; lumpen and proprietors.
The causes of
anti-Semitism are many and diverse. Among the most significant are the
religious motives (in countries belonging to the Christian world expressed in
such accusations as being responsible for the crucifixion of Christ, or
performing ritual slayings of infants) and the fear of being unable to compete
with the activeness of the Jews. This fear assumed a variety of forms: general
fear before the all-encompassing cooperation among the Jews in conjunction with
their ability to penetrate all sphere of social life, from business to politics4;
fear of the Jews grabbing the choice professional positions, perhaps taking
native women due to their ability to achieve a better standard of living and to
their greater responsibility and respect toward their wives and children.
In some cases
these fears were not rationally unfounded. The most grave danger was that Jews
might take over a particular sphere, especially if this sphere was vital for
society's well-being. For instance, if too many Jews become shepherds, doctors,
or traders, and they then decided to leave the country and return to the
Promised Land, this will cause disruptions in the life of the country by
depriving it of essential personnel.
Here I want to
refer to a wonderful essay by Z. Zhabotinskij: "Four Sons." The
author notes that at the basis of anti-Semitism is the conflict between the
fact that initially, when the Jews settle in the territories of other nations,
they are willing to perform work that is important to the native people but
that, for various reasons (including the lack of know-how to do these jobs,
especially complicated ones), is considered "repulsive" by the
natives. Eventually, the native population becomes familiar with these tasks
and one day discovers that the Jews are too powerful in that rather important
area. This leads local authorities to devise all kinds of tricks to get rid of
the Jewish domination. This is what happened to the Jews in Egypt where they
agreed to become shepherds "for every shepherd is an abomination unto the
Egyptians"5; the same took place in the Middle Ages
when Jews turned to trade and money lending.
These reasons
for anti-Semitism can arise from direct contact with the Jews, a situation
characteristic of the so called everyday anti-Semitism, or from widespread
notions of the dangers that the Jewish race holds for other peoples (especially
if the Jews settle within the territories of other nations but in isolation
from them). For instance, in pre-Revolutionary Russia, everyday anti-Semitism
was prevalent in the western part of the empire, in the pales where local
inhabitants came in contact with the Jews. Here envy was combined with
religious superstition and myths of the Jews as devils. As for the greater
share of the Russian population, their contact with the Jews was rather limited
and the roots of their anti-Semitism were primarily religious (the crucifixion
of Christ), superstitious (the ritual slayings), and based on widespread
notions of Jews as the Devil's race capable of inflicting tremendous harm. It
was only after the Revolution, when the Jews left the pales and settled in the
cities, that everyday anti-Semitism became the prevalent form among the masses
of the Russian population.
The diversity
of groups infected with anti-Semitism, as well as the variety of its causes,
can be observed throughout the ages and in all different countries. Of course,
the composition of the groups of people engulfed by anti-Semitism, the strength
of various motives (sometimes a particular reason may be absent altogether for
instance, antipathy against the crucifixion of Christ in non-Christian countries),
and, especially, the severity of anti-Semitic sentiment changes depending on
the culture of a given country and the particular situation it finds itself in.
All this leads
me to conclude that anti-Semitism represents an extremely difficult problem. Is
there a solution at all? Can anti-Semitism ever disappear?
In science,
before solving the problem one attempts to establish existence of a solution.
It was characteristic of seventeenth and eighteenth century science, which
achieved outstanding results in many different fields of human endeavor, to
believe in the absolute possibility from the construction of perpetual motion
machine to the creation of utopian social systems where all people will be
forever happy. Nineteenth century science is more sober, limiting the bounds of
what is possible. During the first part of the nineteenth century, with the
advent of thermodynamics, the impossibility of constructing a perpetual motion
machine becomes clear. Galois's outstanding work of 1821 revealed that equations
of degree greater than four cannot be solved in radicals (by means of a
formula); many other discoveries in mathematics concerned proofs of the
existence of nonexistence of a solution, irrelevant of the actual methods of
finding it. The social sciences were less fortunate. I know of only a single
rigid proof of the impossibility of solving a specific social problem: it
pertains to democratic methods of decision making; the proof was conceived by
K. Arrow in the second half of the twentieth century.
I cannot claim
to have a rigid proof of the impossibility of eradicating anti-Semitism. I only
want to note that it seems to me to be a farfetched possibility. In fact, such
specific causes of anti-Semitism as a priori false accusations of ritualistic
slayings can be dropped; much of the responsibility for the death of Christ can
be lifted. Envy towards the Jews can be subdued as directed specifically
against the Jews and reduced to general envy (in all its might) of one human
being towards another.
The argument
that the Jews are capable of capturing key positions in society, thus
threatening its well-being in case they decide to leave, can be countered by
showing that the number of Jews in each country is too small to capture a
critical mass of the key positions of power; besides, at the time of exodus,
unlike a forced extradition, the majority of Jews remain in a given country.
Moreover, Jewish presence can be considered beneficial in that it forces local
population to become more active. Imposing quotas on the number of Jews in
certain fields creates the danger of unqualified native population streaming
into that area, willing to accommodate their superiors in fighting the
so-called Jewish domination. I realize the ambiguity of all these argument,
since the socioeconomic sphere defies a clear-cut formulation of the conditions
under which protectionism is more advantageous than free trade.
Nevertheless,
a number of features attributed to the Jewish character and used in the
rational justification of anti-Semitism cannot be overcome in principle. I want
to discuss one such anti-Semitic argument prevalent among a very specified
segment of the population: intellectuals. It seems to me that the argument
advanced by this group plays a particularly important role and largely renders
eradication of anti-Semitism impossible.
Intellectuals,
the Programming Sphere, and anti-Semitism.
First, a few
words about the intellectuals. More than any other group, intellectuals not
only observe but can also conceptualize the demands of the situation for the
future developments of society. The distinguishing role of the intellectuals
lies in the integration of a society, in conciliating the authorities with the
masses. Intellectual ideas transform into a force used by the authorities to
legitimate and expand their power.6
This does not
preclude other groups, holding different views formed on their own according,
from playing a very significant role in the life of the country. These groups
may in turn influence the intellectuals, providing them with empirical data.
But it is the intellectuals who represent the driving force behind the ideas
consumed both by those in power and by the masses.
Although
sometimes intellectuals repeat the same argument as other groups, they also
come up with more sophisticated arguments based on actual fact, that reflect
some very real aspects of life, and their concern cannot be written off easily.
It seems that
intellectuals are capable of advancing arguments in favor of anti-Semitism that
have a real basis and are difficult to rebuff. These arguments are directed
specifically at Jews and touch the deep core of the Jewish outlook on the
world. Therefore, as long as the Jewish culture continues to exist we should
not expect to overcome them. Only by accepting the attitudes (and especially
the religion) of the host nation can the Jews hope to put an end to
anti-Semitic persecution. Moreover, certain groups of intellectuals may adhere
to racial theories of anti-Semitism, that is, that there are distinct genetic
characteristics of the Jews. (I shall consider this point below.) In this case,
the solution of the problem lies at worst along the lines of the annihilation
of the Jews or, at best, along the lines of their expulsion from the country.
Before
proceeding to discuss these problems, I want to make the following remark.
There exist certain spheres of society which would, if penetrated by foreign
elements with a radically different system of values, present grave dangers,
for they are in a position to affect the system of values of the country as a
whole (of its major ethnic group), diverting it from its inherent course of
development. To clarify the statement, let us distinguish between the
"programming sphere" and the "executive sphere" of society.
The programming
sphere includes all activities related to the formation of society's genetic
code and its transformation into subsystems, which form the foundation of all
the diverse social structures and their mechanisms of operation. These two
functions, that is, the creation and transformation of the genetic code,
interlinked and having a feedback on on another, comprise the programming
sphere.
Areas
comprising the core of the creation of the genetic code are primarily those
connected with culture: ideologies, art, and basic science; areas such as mass
media, education, political and economic leadership (especially at the higher
levels of the hierarchy and at key positions), and so on, embody the system of
code transformation linked to the first one by mutual interactions.
The executive
sphere encompasses all activities, mental as well as physical, dealing with the
transformation of nature according to the ...passed down... genetic code. The
executive sphere may create feedback that affects the genetic code.
Thus it is the
infiltration of the Jews into the programming sphere that is considered most
dangerous to the development of the native ethnos, since the Jewish system of
values may affect its genetic code. It is precisely in this sense that the Jews
of the Diaspora are viewed as viruses, which, as we know, have no protein
membrane of their own but penetrate the host cell, changing its genetic code.
There is
abundant evidence for this attitude towards the Jews. It assumes many different
and most phantasmagoric forms such as the documents know as "protocols of
the Learned Elders of Zion." Interesting in this respect is a letter
(dated June, 1987) circulating in the U.S.S.R. and addressed to Plenum of the
Central Committee of the CPSU. The letter is signed by three rather prominent
members of Russian intelligentsia: V. G. Brusova, Ph. D. in art history, member
of the Union of Soviet Artists, and recipient of the RSFSR State Prize; G. I.
Litvinova, Ph. D. in law; and T. A. Ponomareva, member of the Writers' Union of
the U.S.S.R. An excerpt from this letter, which denounces the reasons for the
"exploitation" of the Russian people in the U.S.S.R., reads:
Statistics,
objective and scientific, indicate that the much greater sphere of positions at
the top of the social pyramid is presently occupied by individuals belonging to
the Jewish race. . . .
Every one of
us knows from his own personal experience that an illegal possession of the
"brain trust" is not a wild fantasy of the "the Learned Elder of
Zion" but is the most real of realities. A flagrant overtaking of all key,
leading positions in economics, science, and culture, "accelerated"
social growth, have all become a sad reality. . . .
What has this
"international," actually "Jewish brain trust," bestowed
upon us? It has bestowed upon us uncountable damage to the national economy,
trade, ecology, and culture. We were forced to count all these losses and
"mistakes," and their scope was too great. It bears responsibility
for the destruction of agriculture, the dissolution of "unprofitable
villages," the antihuman projects of altering the course of northern
rivers, the destruction of Volga; Baikal is under siege. One experiment after
another, each one throwing us back, making the flywheel of the powerful Soviet
economy perform idle motions. Our system is the most progressive in the world,
and we cannot even feed ourselves; at one time we fed all of Europe, part of
Africa and Asia with a plow and a cart. It turns out we cannot survive without
the help of capitalist powers. And the people work in the sweat of their brow
struggling with new unsolvable problems with suck our finances, labor power,
deeper and deeper into the disastrous whirlpool, inflicting greater and greater
crises, like alcoholism and drug addiction, series of catastrophes, and so on
and so forth.
A new heroic
effort is called for now to pull the country out of its crisis and to clear the
way for progress through perestroika. All this is taking place because
"internationalists" refuse to acknowledge the traditions and the
life-style of the people or the land, which is not at all dear to them (how
much of our best flood lands have sunk under water forever!) nor with the man
himself. Are Russians at the GOSPLAN capable of thinking up a scheme to ensure
workers' wages from the sale of alcohol? No. This is the historically
well-known shadow of a publican robbing and turning people into drunkards.
And the
degradation of theater, the proliferation of rock music, the charlatanism in
painting? And desertion to enemy countries US and Israel and an almost
triumphant return!
No, let us not
be "at the leading edge," let us not be so hasty in our decisions, we
shall not experiment with the most precious thing we hold so dear: our
motherland.7
What is this
mysterious Jewish system of values that is capable of penetrating the
programming sphere and that the intellectuals fear so much? It is the parity of
man and God in the Jewish mentality.
The values
inherent in the Jewish mentality reflect the concept of parity between the Jew
and the forces of the universe. This quality of the Jewish outlook is
especially vivid in Judaism. It is reasonable to think that this religion
agrees with the Jewish mentality: it is doubtful that there could fail to be a
lack of a strong correlation between the type of mentality and the chosen
religion. It follows from the most sacred source of the Jewish faith the Torah
that man is comparable with God as the master of the universe. In fact, it
follows that this Jewish trait should be understood in the broad sense, that
is, not only with respect to God, but also with respect to the environment,
including the leaders of state.
An opposite to
the Jewish system of values could be based on two extremes: either the
subordination of man to the forces governing him (be it God, a leader, or both)
or the superiority of man over the forces of the universe. Most religions and
ideologies profess the first kind of attitude; in fact, I know of no other
religion which claims any kind of equality between man and God. A system of
values proclaiming man's superiority to the forces of nature corresponds to
communist ideology in its pure form. But its actual implementation in many
countries is accompanied by the instituting of authoritarian regime, which is
prone to the dangers of transforming into an ideology directed at subjugating
man to the forces governing him, that is, an ideology fundamentally foreign to
a great number of Jews.
To
substantiate my point regarding the Jewish system of values I want to quote
some passages from the Torah.
Authors of the
Torah had a concept of man as created in God's image and after God's likeness.8
God Himself is presented not as a frozen omnipotent and omniscient force, but
as an evolving entity. Man, endowed with creative powers and free will, expands
God's power. It is by the people and through the people that God implements the
subsequent development of the universe.
Moreover, the
role of man is so great that God stands on a par with some chosen ones and
concludes a covenant with them. According to the covenant, God promises to
multiply the nation coming from Abraham and make Abraham the father of many
peoples; in return a Jew agrees to obey God's commandment obliging all Jewish
makes to be circumcised.
In principle,
a contract between an omnipotent God and man can turn into a pure formality
introduced purely for demagogic purposes. For instance, in the U.S.S.R.,
enterprise management makes a yearly contract with the union, a contract that
is supposed to reflect the interests of the workers. But this contract is
really an empty formality, since the unions are under the complete control of
the government, which is this case is represented by the party and the
managerial body.
A sufficient
condition for a genuine contract between man and God is that is be based on
God's acceptance of His own imperfection, on the one hand, and the greatness of
man and man's indispensability for God as an independent force, on the other.
Moreover, the contract becomes ever-more feasible if a certain equality,
physical as well as intellectual, is established between the two sides.9
Man's physical
strength is affirmed in the legend about the struggle between Jacob and God.10
God could not overcome man in this struggle but could only inflict a minor
wound: "and the hollow of Jacob's thigh was out of joint." And God
said to Jacob: "Thy name shall be called no more Jacob, but Israel: for as
a prince hast thou power with God and with men, and hast prevailed."11
"And
Jacob called the name of the place Peniel: for I have seen God face to face,
and my life is preserved."12
Whatever the
interpretation of this passage is, even assuming that Jacob struggled not with
God but with an angel, Man still was physically on an equal footing with a
heavenly force.
Man's
intellectual comparability with God is affirmed by the authors of the Torah in
the most general terms in the description of Adam after he tastes from the Tree
of Knowledge: Adam even becomes intellectually equal to God. What distinguished
Adam from God is that Adam is mortal; Go banished Adam from the garden of Eden
so he would not taste from the Tree of Life and become immortal.
And the Lord
God said, Behold, the man is become one of us, to know good and evil: and now,
lest he put forth his hand, and take also from the tree of life, and eat, and
live for ever.
Therefore the
Lord God sent him forth from the garden of Eden."13
The authors of
the Torah tell other stories confirming the intellectual comparability between
man and God. When God was enraged at the disobedience of the Jewish people
during their stay in the dessert and decided to annihilate them and replace
them with another nation originating from Moses, Moses argues with God and
persuades Him to preserve the people.
And the Lord
said unto Moses, How long will this people provoke me? and how long will it be
ere they believe me, for all the signs which I have shewed among them?
I will smite
them with the pestilence, and disinherit them, and will make of thee a greater
nation and mightier than they.
And Moses said
unto the Lord, Then the Egyptians shall hear it, (for thou broughtest up this
people in thy might from among them;)
And they will
tell it to the inhabitants of this land: for they have heard that thou Lord art
among this people, that thou Lord art seen face to face, and that thy cloud
standeth over them, and that thou goest before them, by daytime in a pillar of
a cloud, and in a pillar of fire by night.
Now if thou
shalt kill all this people as one man, then the nations which have heard the
fame of thee will speak, saying,
Because the
Lord was not able to bring this people into the land which he sware unto them,
therefore he hath slain them in the wilderness.
And now, I
beseech thee, let the power of my Lord be great, according as thou hast spoken,
saying,
The Lord is
longsuffering, and of great mercy, forgiving iniquity and transgression, and by
no means clearing the guilty, visiting the iniquity of the fathers upon the
children unto the third and fourth generation.
Pardon, I
beseech thee, the iniquity of this people according unto the greatness of they
mercy, and as thou hast forgiven this people, from Egypt even until now.
And the Lord
said, I have pardoned according to thy word."14
The Jewish
attitude toward God as an equal force (in some sense), the defiance and
rejection of idols, all find an explicit manifestation in the Torah in a very
critical attitude toward the leaders of state. Evidence for this can be found
in the sermons concerning the future king of the Jews in the Promised Land
addressed to the Jews during their plight in the desert.
When thou art
come unto the land which the Lord thy God giveth thee, and shalt possess it,
and shalt dwell therein, and shalt say, I will set a king over me, like as all
the nations that are about me;
Thou shalt in
any wise set him king over thee, whom the Lord thy God shall choose: one from
among thy brethren shalt thou set king over thee: thou mayest not set a
stranger over thee, which is not thy brother.
But he shall
not multiply horses to himself, nor cause the people to return to Egypt, to the
end that he should multiply horses: for as much as the Lord hath said unto you,
Ye shall henceforth return no more that way.
Neither shall
he multiply wives to himself, that his heart turn not away: neither shall he
greatly multiply to himself silver and gold.
And it shall
be, when he sitteth upon the throne of his kingdom, that he shall write him a
copy of this law in a book out of that which is before the priests the Levites:
And it shall
be with him, and he shall read therein all the days of his life: that he may
learn to fear the Lord his God, to keep all the words of this law and these
statutes, to do them:
That his heart
be not lifted up above his brethren, and that he turn not aside from the
commandment, to the right hand, or to the left: to the end that he may prolong
his days and his kingdom, he, and his children, in the midst of Israel."15
All in all, it
follows from the preceding discussion that anti-Semitism can hardly be
overcome, that the Jews will for various reasons be incompatible with at least
a great number of the surrounding peoples.
I want to note
in passing that the category of compatibility as a general systems phenomenon
is rather unresearched. Medical science achieved major progress in this area,
both theoretical and practical, only in this century. I mean the classification
of compatible blood groups essential in blood transfusions; organ transplants
accomplished first by donor selection and then by the subsequent integration of
the transplanted organ with the host by means of medicine, and so on. Still,
the problem of compatibility is one of the least-researched areas of medical
science, not to speak of psychology or the social sciences. These observations
apply equally well to the problem of the compatibility of different ethnic
groups.
How can the
"Jewish problem" be solved under these circumstances?
Way of Dealing with the Jewish Problem
First I want
to make some methodological remarks. The solution of the Jewish problem, that
is, the preservation of the Jews as an ethnic entity, has many aspects to it. I
want to examine this issue within the framework of the more general problem in
which the Jewish problem is immersed.16 The general categories to be
prioritized are at least the following:
1. humanity
2. the Jewish race
3. the Jewish state
4. the Jewish family
5. the Jew as an individual.
Assigning priorities to these categories, simple combinatorics shows that there
are 120 five factorial possible combinations. There exist 120 different groups
of people (of course, different in size) distinct in terms of their system of
priorities. For instance, one group would place development of the Jew as an
individual at the forefront, then the Jewish family, the Jewish state, the
Jewish race in fourth place, and mankind in fifth Place. Another group might
assign top priority to mankind, and then in receding order to the Jewish race,
the Jewish state, the Jewish family, and the Jew as an individual. All these
differences manifest themselves at a very practical level, splitting Jewish
public opinion right down the line. As far as Jewish emigration from the
U.S.S.R. is concerned, the first group will assume interest primarily in those
Jews who emigrate to Israel, perhaps even thinking it blameworthy to help Jews not
going to Israel; next they will evaluate the Diaspora Jews in terms of the
latter's views and willingness to extend help to Jews not going to Israel;
finally they will be strongly opposed to sending Israeli invitations to
non-Jews desiring to leave the Soviet Union through that channel. The second
group will proceed to resolve the problem first by advocating for human rights
in general, viewing human rights as a major avenue for Jewish emigration from
the Soviet Union; second, they will defend the right of a Jew from the Soviet
Union to settle in the country of his choice; next, they will encourage Jews to
go to Israel; then they will support Jewish upbringing in Jewish families, and
finally they will help an individual Jew to maintain his Jewish identity (by
giving him the necessary books, for instance).
It is
impossibly to say which of these 120 groups is right. I believe all of them are
needed. Nevertheless, a specific historical situation may call for the
advancement of a particular group as being more conducive to expanding the
variety of ethnic groups comprising mankind.
So, let us for
the sake of definiteness proceed to analyze the Jewish problem from the general
to the specific and examine some major issues within this framework.
First of all,
I want to note that I am a proponent of the concept of that a diversity of
ethnic groups is essential and that the Jewish problem must be solved by
preserving the Jewish race as a distinct ethnic group. I understand that I
cannot prove the validity of my point of view. However, I reject the opposite
point of view that all ethnic groups ought to be mixed together and that
assimilation is the true path, for general philosophical considerations.
It can be said
that differentiation is the chief direction of development; integration
accompanies this process. It is of course very tempting to integrate on the
basis of homogeneity, of unification. However, such a system cannot develop
and, in the end, would not be able to grow or survive. At least, in the past
such systems have failed to grow or survive, whether unorganized or organized,
social worlds. It can be supposed that this will also hold true for the future,
if only because on the one hand, no system can completely anticipate the
future, and because on the other hand, one can function optimally in an
undistinguished world, preserving variety and the possibility of changing
proportions between objects, depending on the situation that arises.
Current
achievements in the field of genetics substantiate the opinions of conservative
scientists that genetic features predispose one to a certain culture but do not
determine it. Interesting in this regard is the book by Charls Lumsden and
Edward Wilson, Genes, Mind, and Culture, in which the authors claim
"the first attempt to trace the development of genes through cultural
consciousness." Their conception "is constructed in such a manner as
to include all types of cultural systems, beginning with the protocultures of
macaques and chimpanzees, up to modern human culture, as well as cultures that
can be born only in the imagination.17
Naturally,
when speaking of genes and culture, one must be extremely cautious, as it is
easy to get wrapped up in all kinds of primitive racial theories. Firstly, it
must be remembered that certain genes influence a person's character, which, in
turn, creates a predisposition to a certain culture, but does not strictly
determine it. Further, from an evolutionary point of view it is advisable to
observe the presence of the entire developing diversity of the genetic
structure and the diversity of cultures of undifferentiated value that
correlate with them as an initial unit. From a global, evolutionary point of
view the preservation and multiplication of both a diversity of genes and a
diversity of cultures is of principal importance.
Advocating
variety in the given sense, I propose the no object within this variety can
be compare with another. Only in a concrete situation and from a certain
point of view can such a comparison be accomplished and can the importance of
the object be ascertained. But such a comparison is only a point in time, and
the dominant issue remains the preservation of diversity.18
I understand that of itself, the preservation of diversity embodies a threat.
The attempt to preserve a particular ethnic group requires extremely guarded
relations with other ethnic groups, if only in order guard against mass
intermingling, as the intentions of another group with a different set of
values are not always clear. Clearly, it is here that we observe the biological
roots for the wariness of certain ethnic groups towards others.
The problem of
preserving diversity becomes particularly complicated, given the mechanism of
selection, because the process of selection focuses on the search for the best
in a given situation. The selection mechanism may turn out to be so strict that
it may at times even destroy diversity. The presence of a variety of ethnic
groups and their inequality in the face of conditions brought on by a certain
historical situation may, because of selection, lead individual groups to
strive for exclusiveness. This is a particular danger for large nations, in
which chauvinism may become a threat to the existence of humanity. Therefore, I
have a certain degree of understanding for the arguments of those who advocate
an intermingling of peoples. Nevertheless, considering the arguments I have
introduced in the beginning of this chapter, it appears to me that the
solutions to the problems of humanity lie in the preservation of a variety of
ethnoses as biological and sociocultural groups,19
and the augmentation of this variety of ethnic groups through their successful
integration, not unification.
From this
point of view, it is essential to resolve the Jewish problem by preserving the
ethnic group. Indeed, acknowledging the necessity for a manifold of ethnic
groups does not determine how they should be organized. The preservation of the
Jewish race poses questions regarding its spatial structuring. In the extreme,
an ethnic group can either be scattered throughout the world or be concentrated
in one region. In general, the existence of a home territory does not exclude
the possibility of living in other areas. Neither does it close the question of
what the proportions between the populations in the home territory and the
peripheries. In other words, here arises a well-known problem of the Jewish
state versus the diaspora. The problem defies an unequivocal solution, for
neither alternative can be proved to be the test.
I do not know
the critical size of the home territory or the critical number of people that
would in effect reduce the role of the Diaspora to zero. In principle, the
presence of statehood for a given ethnic group does not at all mean that...all
eggs should be put in one basket."
I realize that
acknowledging the need for Diaspora is subject to strong criticism, for it
create the danger of Jewish annihilation, especially at times when host
countries experience troubles and look for a scapegoat to appease the native
population. In principle, such appeasement can take place in any country. For
instance, scapegoating in the Soviet Union, which proclaimed the most favorable
conditions for the preservation of the Jewish race, has led to many tragedies.
Furthermore,
there is a danger that the Jews in the Diaspora will be assimilated with the
native population. Moreover, my defense of the Diaspora is inadvertently
colored by the personal desire to justify my decision to live in the Diaspora.
Still, I risk
thinking that there are considerations in favor of combining statehood and the
Diaspora, particularly if the territory of the state is not very large and it
is surrounded by a very hostile environment.20
These considerations include the financial help extended to the Jewish state by
the Jews living in wealthy countries; the influence of the Jewish lobbies in
establishing friendly relations with Israel, and so on and so forth. For
instance, according to Theodor Mommsen's History of Rome, the strength
of Judea was that the Jews had, together with their own state, major
settlements in the most developed cities of the day: Alexandria and Rome.
The danger of
assimilation of the Jews in the Diaspora is not so clear-cut. The assimilation
process in one group of Jews in the Diaspora is accompanied by the
strengthening of the sense of ethnic identity in another, especially prominent
with the appearance of the Jewish state. Of course, the ratio between these two
groups varies from country to country. Perhaps, in free countries where Jews
are not afraid to show their ethnic origin, those rejecting assimilation and
strengthening their ethnic background comprise the greater share of the Jewish
population. This is visible in the United States, where one can scarcely doubt
the growth in interest in Judaism among Jewish youth in the past 30 years.
The Soviet
leadership has done everything possible in order to assimilate the Jews. As
early as the middle of the 1930s Jewish schools were closed in central Russia,
and after the Second World War they were closed in the Ukraine and Byelorussia.
At the end of the 1940s, the central Jewish publishing house and the newspapers
that it published were destroyed, as were Jewish theaters and such. The more
well-known Jewish writers and poets were arrested and killed in Stalinist
torture chambers.
Nevertheless,
the complete assimilation of the Jews was not accomplished. This is because the
assimilation processes of one group of the Jewish population were accompanied
by an increase in the ethnic self-awareness of another, reinforced by the
presence of a Jewish government and world Judaism. However, the main reason why
the assimilation of Jews in the U.S.S.R. has been unsuccessful is because of
the presence of strong anti-Semitic tendencies in the country.
Thus, in the
past several decades the growth of Jewish youth's interest in Judaism can
hardly be doubted. I call this latest phenomenon "the double pyramid
effect": It is usually believed that the older generation, the
grandfathers and grandmothers, are more conservative and religious, and more
closely preserve their ethnic heritage. Their children are usually less
inclined toward this, and their grandchildren become complete atheists with no
regard for their heritage. In the meantime, we see the opposite tendency. The
grandfathers and grandmothers of today, having grown up under the conditions of
the assimilators' ideas and having been fertilized by the anti-Semitic mood of
the masses, were led to forget their Jewish heritage. They attempted to solve
their problems by rejecting the ideas of their Jewish-oriented parents. But
they still cherished a hope of adapting to the milieu of their fathers. Their
grandchildren, to a large extent, understood the illusion of such methods of
problem solving. Thus the pyramid is upside-down---there is the tendency that
its tip will again be Judaism.
Let me put
forth some thoughts on the attempt to generalize the history of the Jews in the
Diaspora.
There arise
four possible combinations generated by two factors: the degree of hostility of
the environment toward the Jews, and the size of the Jewish population. In
rather simplistic terms, the degree of hostility can be denoted as either
strong or weak, and the size of the population as either sufficient or
insufficient in having the critical mass to preserve the Jewish identity.
Under
favorable surroundings but with the size of the population small (in a sense of
lacking the critical mass needed to maintain distinct identity), Jews dissolve
among the native peoples. This is what happened with the old Jewish settlements
in China. Despite hostility from the environment, Jews in sufficient numbers
can preserve their ethnicity for a limited period of time. An example of this
situation are the Jews of Spain during the time of the Inquisition, when they managed
to survive as Marranos. Perhaps this is also true for Russian Jews, especially
if we account for the emigration of the active part of the Jews having Jewish
identity. The combination of favorable conditions and sufficient size is
evident in Jewish communities in England, the United States, and some Latin
American countries. Nevertheless, the historical perspective of this experience
is too narrow to make any definite conclusions about the prospects of the Jews
in these countries. A hostile environment in conjunction with a small
population practically leads to the disappearance of the Jews. Modern-day
Poland is an example of this situation.
All this leads
me to conclude that the Jewish problem probably defies solution if the Jews
want to stay an independent ethnic group in a foreign country. It means that
there is the need for a Jewish state.
It is stressed
in the Torah that the Jewish people ought to have a land of their own, and God
promises this and leads them to the land of Canaan.
Of course, the
last thesis may be disputed. The Jews survived in the Diaspora, as did the
Gypsies (who had no land of their own) and the Armenians. But past experience,
both of the Jew and non-Jews, is no guarantee for the future. The lack of
statehood could, in certain critical situation be fatal for a particular ethnic
group, especially with the development of inexpensive means of mass destruction
and the imbalance between the strength of the armed killers and their
defenseless victims.
I further
believe that statehood is a necessary (but perhaps insufficient) condition for
the stable long-run maintenance of an ethnic institutions stemming from it.
History show that without statehood and without their own territory, Jews have
repeatedly become the objects of oppression, ranging from attempts at their
direct physical annihilation (at times very successful) to their expulsion from
the country where they lived. It is enough to recall the Torah to illustrate
this. Some rulers even invited Jews to live their lands and created favorable
conditions for them to do so. But then, when the Jews became strong and began
to play a noticeable role in the country's growth, at best they were asked to
leave and at worst, attempts were made to exterminate them.
Thus
"Abraham dwelt in the land of the Philistines many years as a
stranger."21 He lived there in peace under King
Abimelech. Then, in the days of famine, Abraham's son Isaac, came to the land
of the Philistines. He was received joyously. Isaac flourished in his affairs.
And the man
waxed great and he grew more and more until be became very great: he acquired
flocks and herds, and a large household, so that the Philistines envied him.
And the Philistines stopped up all the wells which his father's servants had
dug in the days of his father Abraham, filling them with earth. And Abimelech
said unto Isaac: Go from us; for thou art much mightier than we. And Isaac
departed thence.22
Joseph, who
ended up by Egypt by accident, was singled out by Pharaoh. Joseph's fame was
great and he did much for the flourishing of Egypt and the strengthening of
Pharaoh. When Joseph informed Pharaoh that his, Joseph's, father and brothers
had come to Egypt,
Pharaoh spoke
unto Joseph saying: Thy father and thy brothers are come unto thee; the land of
Egypt is before thee; in the best of the land make thy father and thy brothers
to settle; let them dwell in the land of Goshen. And if thou knowest any able
men among them, then make them rulers over my livestock.23
After Joseph
died, the children of Israel were fruitful and increased abundantly, and
multiplied, and waxed exceedingly mighty; and the land was filled with them.
Now there arose a new king over Egypt who knew not Joseph. And he said unto his
people: Behold, the people of the children of Israel are too many and too
mighty for us; come, let us deal shrewdly with them, lest they multiply and it
come to pass that there befallenth us a war, they then join themselves unto our
enemies and fight against us, and gain ascendancy over the land.24
Then Pharaoh
charge all his people, saying, "Every son that is born ye shall cast into
the River.25
The end of
this story is well known. Jews succeeded in leaving Egypt, overcoming enormous
difficulties in the process and under the threat of complete disappearance.
The "Joseph
Model," as Professor Boris Moishezon termed it, is instructive through and
through. It has been frequently replayed; in just this century, quite
successfully in Germany, the U.S.S.R., and Poland. Who know where it will flare
up next?
Thus I share
the opinion of those who believe that a Jewish state is needed. I also agree
with those who had already realized by the end of the nineteenth century that
it is needed now. There was time when God promised Abraham the Land of Canaan
for the great nation that shall spring from him. But God said that the time has
not come yet, that three hundred years are needed "for the iniquity of the
Amorites is not yet full."26 The Holocaust demonstrated the validity
of the Zionist perspective that the time for establishing a Jewish state had
arrived.
Let us further
assume that all my arguments in favor of combining the Diaspora with the Jewish
state are wrong, and that all Jews ought to live in the Jewish state. There are
still difficult problems arising in this connection concerning the creation of
such a state.
I anticipate
the question of a perplexed reader: "What is all this discussion about the
creation of a Jewish state since such a state, namely Israel, already
exists?"
Indeed I share
the opinion of those who believe that a Jewish state is needed, and needed now.
I also share the opinion of those who see in Israel the best solution to this
question at present (more on this point later.) However, I cannot consider this
solution the only possible one as far as solving the problem of Jewish
statehood as a whole is concerned.
The
establishment of a Jewish state could go in at least three different
directions: with a view to the past, the present, or the future.
With a view to
the past, the establishment of a Jewish state is linked with Israel, the land
of our ancestors, the Promised Land. This great idea managed to grab hold of
millions of Jews and to succeed. In 1948 Israel was created. In a short period
of time, Israel established a democratic system (in spite of a hostile environment
and frequent wars), introduced its own agriculture and industry, and put
together the pride of Israel: one of the best armies in the world. This is just
one more proof that the potential of this nation is so great as to be able to
handle new fields that for ages were thought of as foreign to the Jewish
people.
On the road to
realizing this idea enormous difficulties were encountered, because the state
was created among hostile Arabs supplied with modern weaponry by the great
powers. Israel, even if it gathered all the Jews, would be hard pressed to
produce all the various kinds of modern weapons in quantities sufficient to
rebuff possible Muslim bloc countries; the size of the territory makes Israel
even more vulnerable.
Take into
account that the Arab countries have a culture that predisposes them toward
authoritarian regimes and rather awkward economic development and aggression;
their economic prosperity is ephemeral, for it hinges on the abundance of one
natural resource: oil.27 Israel, on the other hand, possesses a
culture predisposed toward pluralistic democracy and its counterpart, effective
economic development and a peaceful foreign policy. Therefore, Israel will, for
a long time, represent and unpleasantly successful model for Arab countries.28
The military dependence of little Israel on a great power in an age of advanced
armaments will remain strong, yet great powers have their own interests and may
sacrifice their satellites for the sake of these.
Economic
problems and the military danger aggravate the problem of attracting and
keeping Jews in Israel when they are not faced with any immediate danger in the
Diaspora. These problems complicated the everyday lives of Israelis and make
the task of combining this everyday life with a general attachment to the great
idea of statehood significantly more difficult.
Looking toward
the present, a Jewish state could be created by the purchase of land (I believe
projects were made to buy land in Kenya, Canada, or elsewhere). However, the
idea of creating a Jewish state by this means was not realized further, because
there was no tradition to uphold it. For this reason, aggravated by the
difficulties of existing in what might well be a hostile environment,) the set
of solutions to the problem of Jewish statehood through Jewish autonomy within
the borders of an existing great power is unacceptable. It should first of all
be noted that the large democratic countries do not have such autonomous
national entities: these countries primarily develop a culture innate to that
country. If an ethnic group with its own history, and especially its own land,
happens for some reason to be situated in the territory of such a country, it
separated into an independent state; an example of this is the separation of
Norway from Sweden. Autonomous national entities do exist in authoritarian
empires, but their stability always hangs by a thread because the government
nation attempts to assimilate them for the purpose of controlling them (it is
good to have unity of language and culture) as well as for the purpose of
preventing separatist movements. Therefore, even if Soviet Jews had received
the Crimea instead of Birobidzhan because it is still within the totalitarian
Soviet Union, life would nevertheless have been unbearable there. Moreover,
autonomy within authoritarian empires can be revoked at any time.
With a view
toward the future, a Jewish state could be created using pioneering ideas based
on new technological means. Let's say, for example, a state could be
established on floating artificial island, with inexpensive thermonuclear
energy drawing a unlimited water resources. Already today, on a small scale,
such artificial islands are used for the extraction of oil, and it has been
suggested that they might be built in the coastal water of Japan and Saudi
Arabia on a larger scale. But maintaining the equilibrium of large-scale
floating artificial islands would require a lot of energy.
Other
fantastic ideas of a Jewish state speak of Jews settling in space.29
This method is perhaps fraught with even more difficulties, in view of the
problems of adapting human physiology to prolonged stays in outer space.
These kinds of
outrageous ideas draw on the Jewish pioneering spirit and might be attractive
for a number of Jews who have actively joined in civilization. Recall that the
Jewish pioneering spirit has a long history, perhaps longer than the idea of
the Promised Land. If we study the biblical history of the Jews, then it's
clear (naturally in the sense of a hypothesis) that the Jews have been carriers
of innovative ideas. Moishezon's series of articles entitled "The Riddles
of Ancient Civilizations" in the journal People and Land nos. 1, 2,
3, is enormously interesting in this connection. Let me just cite one excerpt
from this series, reminding the reader that anthropologically Jews belong to
the Armenoid type.
Approximately
12,000 years ago sharp changed in the life of people of the earth began. The
first dwellings appeared and the first fortified settlements, as well as
decorations and rock vessels. The first steps were taken toward agriculture and
animal husbandry. Archaeologists call these events the "Neolithic
revolution." The beginning of the neolithic revolution is now connected
with the so-called Natufisk culture on the territory of Israel. There the first
city was found, the town of Jericho.
Contemporary
data on the development of the Neolithic and subsequent cultures so that,
viewed as a whole, it was a process which was constantly expanding in time and
scope. New hearths arose and vanished, but in the course of time the Neolithic
revolution encompassed all new areas. First northern Mesopotamia and the
southern regions of Anatolia, Greece, and the Balkans, and later the
Trans-Caucasus, western and northern Iran, southern Tukmenia and southern
Mesopotamia were included. From about the seventh century b.c. in Anatolia and
northern Mesopotamia, cultures began to develop in which pottery and the
beginning elements of metallurgy can be found. These cultures correspond to the
so-called Halkolite epoch. From them, once again waves of progress spread to
the west, east, and south.
The next
archaeological period is the Bronze Era (from 4000 b.c.) which it seems,
undisputably had its source in the Gassul-Beersheva culture and the subsequent
cultural centers of northern Syria, Sumer, and the Caucasus. An analogous
picture is drawn as well from analysis of the archaeological and ancient
written record of the so-called Iron Age (from about 1200 b.c.). Aside from the
spatial and temporal continuity of the development begun by the Neolithic
revolution, archaeologist have found a variety of further links and
coincidences of style in cultures separated from one another, in addition to
simultaneity in a number of significant changes and innovations. It sometimes
seems that the process of humankind's progress was only locally determined by
freedom of choice and coincidences, but as a whole was as if coordinated and
directed. Such an almost mystical sensation can be made rational if we assume
the presence of a certain continuity and connection with some stable portion of
the active human element, which intuitively goes beyond the unanimated
evidences of archeology.
The evidences
of ancient sculpture described earlier and the deformation of skulls as early
as Neolithic times, as well as the anthropological correlation between
metallurgical centers, simply and clearly point in only one direction: the
stable portion in the process of cultural evolution in the Neolithic and
subsequent eras, that which determined their continuity and connection, was a
people anthropologically belonging to the Armenoid type. Moreover, the Armenoid
representation of kings and gods and the connection between the Armenoid
deformed heads with their conception of nobility makes a still-stronger
assumption highly likely. In very ancient times (approximately from 10,000
years b.c.) the Armenoids were one and the same as the upper class, at least in
the central part of the Near Eastern cultural center, and their expansion
basically corresponded with the process of that center's widening.30
I have briefly
described the arguments for and against the creation of a Jewish state
according to three possible criteria. In summary the idea of founding a Jewish
state based on the first criterion, a view toward the past, succeeded because
it was based on a very powerful tradition and, moreover, was technically
attainable. The second criterion, the view to the present, apparently failed
because in it there was no cementing idea flowing either from the past or
toward the future (but connected with the past), and the pragmatism of the
present prevailed. The third criterion, a view toward the future, may have a
potential for survival from the point of view of exploiting tradition, but it
must first of all become technically feasible. Thus for example, for floating
islands in open waters cheap energy is needed in great quantities. Controlled
thermonuclear reaction is a potential source of unlimited cheap energy from
independent (in the sense of not belonging to anybody) water. But alas! How
many more years will it be until this is possible? Scientists put the earliest
date in the twenty-first century.
Thus, only the
first path to creating a Jewish state remains realistic; the one that was
realized. Furthermore, assume that the Jewish State of Israel is the sole
solution to the problem and that all Jews, that is, all Jews not wanting to
assimilate, must live in Israel. How can one organize a mass exodus of Jews
from the Diaspora to Israel, if they are not yet faced with a critical
situation in Diaspora countries?
It is
extremely difficult for me, not having been born in Israel and not possessing
deep roots there, and with the opportunity to live under favorable conditions
in the Diaspora, to move to country that is a besieged fortress requiring
toughness of spirit from the newly arrived and enormous faith in the
possibility of a long-term blossoming of Israel. The immigration of Jews to
Israel requires time: time to change the psychology of the people---a factor as
objective as their situation in the Diaspora.
The Torah
contains many deep reflection on the psychology of Jews faced with radical
decisions. When God led the Jews out of Egypt to the Promised Land, he could
have, brought them immediately by way of a short path through the land of the
Philistines. Another path was chosen and here is what the Torah has to say on
this point: "Now when Pharaoh let the people go, God did not lead them by
way of the land of the Philistines, although it was nearer; for God said, 'The
people may have changed of heart when they see war, and return to Egypt.' So
God led the people round-about, by way of the wilderness at the Sea of
Reeds."31
As everyone
knows, it took the Jewish people forty years to walk through the wilderness to
the Promised Land. This was a punishment to all who had scorned God. They were
frightened by difficulties, since they had grown up in Egypt in slavery; they
were afraid of enemies; they had tasted the benefits of the good life, which
they had had before the arrival of the last Pharaoh. Torah speaks on this
point:
Your carcasses
shall fall in this wilderness; and all that were numbered of you, according to
your whole number, from twenty years old and upward, which have murmured
against me.
Doubtless ye
shall not come into the land, concerning which I sware to make you dwell
therein, save Caleb the son of Jephunneh, and Joshua the son of Nun.
But your
little ones, which ye said should be a prey, them will bring in, and they shall
know the land which ye have despised.
But as for
you, your carcasses, they shall fall in this wilderness.
And your
children shall wander in the wilderness for forty years, and bear your
whoredoms, until your carcasses be wasted in the wilderness.
After the
number of days in which ye searched the land, even forty days, each day for a
year, shall ye bear your iniquities, even forty years, and ye shall know my
breach of promise.32
Conclusion
This is not to
excuse myself from the moral guilt for leaving the U.S.S.R. on an Israeli visa
and yet not going to Israel.
It was my
right to leave the Soviet Union and go to any other country that I liked and
that was prepared to accept me. But the entire question was how to emigrate.
There is an ugliness in much an emigration first of all because it was
accomplished through a lie. Of course, much can be said to justify my decision
on this point. First of all, the ban on lying is not one of the Ten
Commandments (the Torah mentions the unacceptability of lying only in the book
of Leviticus, 19:11): and how much our forefathers lied, especially in foreign
lands.33 But for me, a lie is a lie regardless of its purpose. And
if a man is too weak and happens to lie, he should not justify it but repent.
In leaving the
U.S.S.R., I also used the slogans under which a group of steadfast Soviet Jews
began the campaign for permission to emigrate to their historical homeland, to
the Jewish state. They could resoundingly say to me: Why didn't you organize
your own movement for emigration from the U.S.S.R. but not to Israel? It seems
to me that such a question has serious foundations.
The Soviet
leaders were not allowing Jews to go to Israel. They were cynically selling
Jews, who were regarded as government property34
to the U.S. in exchange for détente and the benefits arising thereby. Of
course, formally it was more comfortable for the Soviet leaders to permit the
Jews to go to Israel. It gave them the opportunity to deprive those emigrating
of Soviet citizenship even before they left, and so to avoid all kinds of
trouble that the emigrants could cause it they should want to return or to
visit friends or relatives in the U.S.S.R.
This
revocation of citizenship played upon public opinion, for the revocation was
dependent on emigration to a state with whom the U.S.S.R. did not have
diplomatic relations.35 In the eyes of other Soviet peoples
having their historic homeland within the borders of the Soviet state, the
emigration of Jews to Israel justified Jews' right to emigrate (as it did for
Germans; Armenian emigration was explained by the fact that they were not born
in the U.S.S.R. but was brought there by their parents after the Second World
War). Moreover, if Lithuanians or Ukrainians wanted to leave, the government
could always claim that these were within the boundaries of the U.S.S.R., and
that if they want to reunite with their countrymen then they may be invited to
return to their homelands in the U.S.S.R.
Fortunately,
starting in October 1989, Jewish emigration from the Soviet Union has taken a
different course. While still in the Soviet Union, Jews are now allowed to
specify the country where they wish to emigrate. Presently, new problems have
confronted the Soviet Jewry. Fearing unrest stemming from worsening economic
conditions, nationalistic unrest in the republics, and the possibility of
Jewish pogroms, the number of Jews who want to emigrate right away has risen
dramatically, perhaps of the order of two hundred thousand. The problem now is
which countries can and are willing to take these people in such huge numbers.
What
conclusions are to be drawn from all that has been said? The reader should once
more reexamine his views on the place of Jews in the world, should try to
better understand the strengths and weaknesses of various conceptions guiding a
Jew in preserving his ethnicity of choosing his country of habitat. But in any
case, whatever his personal choice is, let it not be regarded as the sole
possible path for solving such a complex problem.
Notes and References
9
The
Solzhenitsyn Phenomenon
I want to
conclude this part of the book with a short chapter devoted to Aleksandr I.
Solzhenitsyn. His art, it seems to me,
synthesizes our discussion of the two previous sections. I regard Solzhenitsyn
as a Russophile of nationalistic variety, meaning that he considers the values
of the Russian people to be diametrically opposed to Western values. In addition, he shares the anti-Semitic
views of those who hold the Jews to be at the root of all Russia's misery.
In my opinion,
some of the most interesting criticism of Solzhenitsyn, revealing his
contradictory nature, comes from the pen of Alexander Yanov. I therefore chose to present my views of
Solzhenitsyn as a critical review of Yanov's ideas. Our discussion here will be limited to Yanov's latest thoughts on
the subject, expounded in the Russian version of his book Russian Ideas and
the Year 2000.[91]
This book
contains the result of many years' reflections on the fate of Russia, the
future of its peoples, on Russia's attitudes toward the West, and so on, as
well as observations on the role the russophiles play in the resolution of
these issues. Probably one of the most
interesting issues raised by Yanov in this book is the theme of Solzhenitsyn: it occupies more that one-sixth of the
book. In analyzing the work of
Solzhenitsyn, Yanov concentrates on past and present ideals common to all
russophiles and on the specific ideals characteristic of certain circles. Not all of Solzhenitsyn's ideas are shared
by other russophiles, and a few of them, as for example his suggestion that the
empire should be disperse, even generate animosity. Russophiles who wish to preserve the empire, or even to preserve
Russia alone, cannot concur with Solzhenitsyn that it would have been
advantageous for Russia, surrounded as it is by industrial and industrializing
nations (especially such a forbidding enemy as China), to become an agrarian
nation. (I do not wish to exaggerate
the role of these differences of opinion.
The views of extremists before they come into power can differ markedly
from the more sober views that they may adopt after gaining power. Thus it was the Bolsheviks, for example, who
before the Revolution were the most blatant critics of the Russian empire,
which they claimed represented the imprisonment of the masses. Not long after the Revolution, however, they
did everything possible in order to preserve and even to expand the Russian
empire.) What's more, the basic political
orientation of Solzhenitsyn's works harmonizes with the needs of today's russophiles,
and is at least close to them in the method of reiterating the past views of
slavophiles.
Yanov makes
use of a special literary device in order to illustrate the close ties between
Solzhenitsyn's views and the views of the slavophiles of the past century. First, Yanov quotes Solzhenitsyn and
Aksakov, a nineteenth-century slavophile with corresponding references. Here's the text of the quotes:
You (the
leaders of the U.S.S.R.) have unshakable power, a strong, separate closed
party, the army, the police, industry, transport and communications systems,
mineral and petroleum resources, a monopoly on foreign trade, control of the
value of the ruble---but let the people breathe, think and develop![92]
"The people want one thing for themselves: the freedoms of life, spirit, and
speech. Because they do not interfere
in state power, they do not wish the state to interfere in the independent life
of their spirit."[93]
Then Yanov
writes:
Doesn't this
tirade sound as if it had been written by one person? Only the first part, by the way, belongs to Solzhenitsyn. The second part was addressed to completely
different leaders at a completely different time. One-hundred-thirty years ago, Konstantin Aksakov recommended to
the leader of the orthodox government the same thing that Solzhenitsyn
recommends to the Soviet leaders: Take
for yourselves complete power, but give the people complete freedom. The people will not interfere in politics---Aksakov
and Solzhenitsyn promise---they only want to "breathe, think, and
develop" freely.[94]
As
Solzhenitsyn has admitted and as Yanov has later shown, slavophilism has a
typical fundamentalist, anti-Western character. These views are not only the prerogative of Russia/U.S.S.R.; they exist and even flourish in several
other countries.
It is probably
even insulting to Solzhenitsyn, the greatest Russian writer of this century,
that he's called "Ayatollah Solzhenitsyn". But is this really unfair?
Solzhenitsyn's program, which he repeatedly announces ("Letter to
the Leaders of the Soviet Union," a speech at Harvard,) and with his
literary works of recent years differ very little from Khomeini's views before
his ascension to power. What
Solzhenitsyn would do if he became the ruler of Russia, the spiritual leader,
is not very difficult to guess.
Solzhenitsyn-esque
fundamentalism and anti-Western sentiment, which are the keystones of his view
of the world, emerge most clearly in his conviction that, in the urban,
industrial path of Western development, the true path of Russia's development
lies in the people's return to the soil.
Unfortunately, Yanov, concentrating on the more important aspects of
Solzhenitsyn-esque fundamentalism, fails to bring out this point with adequate
emphasis. In my view, without a rather
precise understanding of this point it becomes more difficult to understand the
intricacies of Solzhenitsyn's view of the world and the reasons underlying his
anti-Western bent, regardless of whether Solzhenitsyn himself expresses these
views distinctly or indistinctly (explicitly or implicitly). I will therefore mention that Western
development has been extroverted, that is, focused on the attainment of
individual happiness mainly through social changes based on scientific and
technological progress, and on the dynamics of the social organization of
society. This of course presupposes the
development of the individual; the
primacy of the individual is recognized.
In other words, society exists for the individual, the individual does
not exist for society (this will surely grate on my Russian-speaking
readers). We are talking about the
development of the individual, not of the egotist; that is, about the development of the human being who also
recognizes others as human beings, and who does not view them simply as
"cogs in the wheel" existing only in order to play out his whims.
In contrast to
the course of Western development is introversion, with a focus on the
internal development of the individual.
This course is naturally associated with conservative production and an
immobile political system.
The complexity
of the situation lies in that the conservative position has a valid point. It has hardly been proven that a nation's
focus on its industrial development is the only true path. Technical progress can lead to uncontrollable
consequences not only in connection with environmental pollution, the potential
destruction of humanity from nuclear missiles, or its potential incineration by
lasers installed on satellites. The
danger of technological progress hails from the impossibility of proving that
significant technical achievements will be used for the good of humanity: we say that research on the acceleration of
subatomic particles will not lead to a global conflagration, that discoveries
in genetic engineering will not yield ubiquitous invisible monsters, and that
computers will not lead to the development of humanity on some blind course,
but we cannot guarantee it. More than
two thousand years ago the Indians understood the danger of technical progress,
and built a civilization that rejected technical development and focused on the
individual's internal development.
In saying
this, I do not wish to refute the expediency of an industrial course of
development. I simply wish to say that
one should not be so ambitious and arrogant as to believe that the Western
model of the development of civilization is the only feasible one.
On the other
hand, one should not suppose that the introverted, "rural" course of
development is the only true one. The
absence of scientific and technological progress leads not only to illness and
hunger, but in a longer time-frame, it threatens the existence of humanity
because of possible cosmic catastrophes.
(In regard to this, I'd like to mention that one of the greatest
contributions of Russian philosophers and scholars consists of the creation,
development, and practical realization of cosmic philosophy. I have in mind primarily the names of two
well-known Russian: Nikolaj F. Fedorov
and Konstantin E. Tsiolkovsky.)
The course of
development one or another country elects to follow during one or another
period of its history is the choice of the people themselves. Do the Russian people want to follow
Solzhenitsyn's course? He does not even
entertain the thought that the Russian people could choose another course. He is imbued with the faith that the rural
course has been preordained by Russia's fate and history. As Yanov demonstrates, Solzhenitsyn does not
allow for the possibility that the patriotism of the Russian people permits various
viewpoints regarding the country's course of development, and that it is
impossible to prove or disprove that one of them is true or false from a
universal standpoint.
Under these
conditions, the pluralistic mechanism, in conjunction with the democratic one,
to a large extent supports the people in the free choice of the course of their
development and its shifts during times of change. Richly quoting Solzhenitsyn, Yanov notes that political pluralism
is alien to Solzhenitsyn, a profound believer in the existence of a single true
path in the development of humanity.
Solzhenitsyn's basis for such views lies in his disregard for
philosophical pluralism. Yanov rightly
recalls the words from Solzhenitsyn's article "Our Pluralists,"
"there is one truth."[95] It is possible that, in the foreign term "pluralism," at
the basis of which lies a conception of the impossibility either of proving or
disproving the validity of answers to cardinal questions connected with one or
another general course of development, Solzhenitsyn sees undertones of the
Russian word pluvat' (literally 'to spit', meaning to degrade or
disregard in some negative way).
All of
Solzhenitsyn's judgements, as analyzed by Yanov, do not simply concern the
reworking of an ideal for the development of Russia. Yanov analyzes them in a broader sense in critically evaluating
Russia's current situation, while also searching for the sources that have led
to the present state of affairs. There
is no denying that the Bolshevik Revolution has brought Russia more than a
little grief and, in the end, has plunged the country into stagnation. Everything leads back to the question of
where to seek the causes that resulted in the victory of the October
Revolution. The answer to this question
is closely interwoven with the matter of where to look in order to find a way
out of current difficulties.
Yanov
demonstrates in detail that Solzhenitsyn does not view the causes of modern
Russia's dilemma as having come from within Russia herself, but rather from the
influence of the pernicious West, which introduced a foreign element into
Russia: Western communistic ideas.
Here we can
already see the beginning of a tendency to look to Jews as the cause of
Russia's misfortune. In this book,
Yanov demonstrates most convincingly that Solzhenitsyn is infected with
anti-Semitism. It is sufficiently clear
from the examples of Israel Lazerevich Parvus (whose real name is Gelfand) in Lenin
in Zurich, and Dmitry (Mordekxaya, Mordke) Bogrov in The Red Wheel
that Solzhenitsyn seeks the diabolical powers that, like dark whirlwinds, have
been sent to destroy Russia, primarily in Jews.
Yanov presents
a detailed examination of the book Lenin in Zurich in a separate
section. Here, Solzhenitsyn openly says
that Lenin was alien to the genuine interests of Russia, that he was only half
Russian (he was actually only one-quarter Russian). Also, Yanov convincingly demonstrates, using numerous references
to the book in question, that the primary source of evil was a man who stood
behind Lenin, who "according to Lenin's own confession, surpassed him in
every aspect." This man was
Parvus. Properly speaking, Parvus was
not even a human being, but, as is evident from the epithets bestowed on him by
Solzhenitsyn and quoted by Yanov, a being with "a brilliant behemoth
head," "a seismic feeling of inner nature," "a ruthless and
inhuman mind," who in addition had "wandered about Europe as
Ahasverus for 25 years." But
according to Solzhenitsyn, the Devil can take on various forms. And so, in The Red Wheel Solzhenitsyn
paints a portrait of another Jew, Mordke Bogrov, who, having murdered Russia in
the presence of Stolypin, confesses to the "shrill and steady
three-thousand-year summons" of his race.[96]
This is how
Yanov analyzes Solzhenitsyn's devilization of Bogrov (the figures in
parentheses correspond to the volume number of Solzhenitsyn's collected works
as published in Paris in 1983, and the page number of the corresponding
quotation):
The
devilization of Bogrov, if one can express it this way, occurs gradually, is
introduced carefully, at first using barely noticeable features. Here Bogrov hunches over "to crawl
silently and unseen between the revolution and the police" (12:124). After a few more pages his companion
suddenly sees him "with his two upper canines elongated, slightly
protruding forward when his upper lip was raised during conversation"
(12:131). Again after a few more pages
he will creep along a pole: "a
completely smooth one without a notch, without a jag. . . without any
support" (12:138), "rubbing against it with his whole body to crawl
off into improbability" (12:141).
A page further his similarity to a snake increases: Bogrov "with a compressed and elongated
head always slightly bent to one side, and with lips constantly parted"
(12:142). Neither a forked tongue nor
venom is mentioned yet, only "the narrow head, a little to one side"
(12:143), only "he bewitches like the singing of a rare bird, neck
extended, and at such moments even seems kind to his enemies" (12:144),
although---and here the metaphor becomes dangerously candid for the first
time---"he wanted only to let fall a drop of enfeebling poison between
them" (12:144)
Now there is
no doubt in the reader's mind: before
him is a snake. And Bogrov continues to
creep along the fateful pole, "he twisted, writhed" (12:157) with his
"bewitching glances, his faintly striped head a little to one side"
(12:158). The author even senses
"how the muscular coils are already tired" (12:163). But all this time "the few drops needed
for that fateful moment should be stored up, overflowing---in the mind? in the gut?
in the tooth" (12:249).
This is how Stolypin sees Bogrov, when the "fateful moment" at
last unfolds: to bite "he moved as
if wriggling, thin and long, in a tail-coat, black. . . a long-faced, young
Jew" (12:248). He has bitten,
"gliding by on his black back, he ran off" (12:249). The image of the Jew has merged with the
image of the snake. Is the snake only
to be understood in the biblical sense?[97]
Accusing Jews
of being an alien influence is not new for Russia. Neither is the russophilic bent of an author; even such great writers as Dostoyevski were
not strangers to anti-Semitism. Theirs
was not ordinary anti-Semitism, it was ideological. The opinion that Dostoyevski's anti-Semitism stemmed from his
belief that the Russian masses were God's chosen people is very
widespread. This philosophy turns out
to be incompatible with the conception of the chosen people held by Judaism, a religion which was a precursor of Christianity.
The
overglorification of the rural lifestyle, anti-Westernism, anti-Semitism, and
monism, which have been discussed above, do not play such a great role in
Solzhenitsyn's philosophy, or indeed in the philosophy of slavophiles in
general, simply by chance. On paper, it
is relatively easy to criticize the West, Jews, and pluralism and to glorify
one's native people. This is logically
associated with a nation's sense of morality: it is theoretically more difficult to draw parallels between a people's
morality and an urban industrial society.
It is not simply by chance that Yanov, again lavishly quoting
Solzhenitsyn-esque anti-Western statement, concludes with Solzhenitsyn's quote
that "a society in which political parties function cannot increase its
morality."
In actuality,
Solzhenitsyn and the russophiles perfectly understand the necessity of a
revival of morals. Indeed, without a
revival of morals it is difficult to anticipate successful long-term
development. Morality, with its
unconditional requirements such as "Thou shalt not murder" and
"Thou shalt not steal," provides each individual with a basic notion
of proper behavior in light of the unknowable future. It provides the individual with the opportunity to fashion his
moral potential so that he is not caught up in the immediate effects of the
moment. Morality provides (especially
to good people) the understanding that one is not meant to know what
catastrophic results may be caused by the murder of even one dishonest person
in the name of the salvation of a thousand others.
The point,
however, is not that democratically oriented groups do not notice the vitally
important role of morality. The people
who compose these groups demonstrate higher moral ideals through their own
behavior. Academician Andreg Sakharov
and others concerned with the fate of Russia focus primarily on the creation of
political and legal conditions that preserve the individual. The history of humanity has demonstrated
that, if political and legal structures guaranteeing the sanctity of the
individual are not created, and the individual's fate depends largely on the
grace of the leaders, then, even given the most refined structures for
maintaining morals, political leaders will not be saints. An overwhelming majority of leaders will not
restrain their power but will suppress the individual and make a slave of him.
Yanov
thoroughly observes Solzhenitsyn's evolution and reveals how, repeating the
famous tenets of certain russophilic circles, Solzhenitsyn rejects the creation
of a political system in which the leaders would be checked by the political
participation of the people and reinforced in designated political
institutions, and becomes a vehement advocate of an authoritarian regime. This thought deeply penetrates all of the
chapters that Yanov has devoted to analyzing Solzhenitsyn's works. In particular, Yanov notes that his praise
of the authoritarian regime involuntarily leads Solzhenitsyn to the old
slavophilic idea of "two freedoms":
internal and external. Solzhenitsyn, also, believes that one may be dependent
politically, but that this is not so important: it is important to preserve internal independence and spiritual
freedom. In summarizing Yanov's
criticism of Solzhenitsyn's views, it can be said that an internal freedom
coupled with an external lack of freedom is the ascetic's destiny. But to build a world assuming that every
person can become an ascetic ignores the enormous force exerted by the
limitations built into our psychological nature, since the emotional
disposition of an individual is largely genetically predetermined to resist
slavery; blessed are those who are free
of the predisposition of cultivate in themselves asceticism.
Is stands to
reason that if there is only a legal system, and morals are absent,
society may wallow in bureaucracy and callousness. Incalculable paperwork would be created, as people were forced to
run back and forth to judges in order to resolve their differences. Hostility among people would increase
although it would take on legal forms.
But a certain remark made by Valery N. Chalidze, a staunch defender of
rights, comes to mind: the greatness of
rights is that they create minimal guarantees for the defense of the
individual.
Overidealization
of the rural lifestyle, and particularly of the fact that it is accompanied by
morality, largely determines relations to the intelligentsia and to education
in general. The term obrazovanshchina
[a derogatory term for an intellectual with a superfluous education---trans.],
demonstrating an extremely negative view of the intelligentsia, was widely used
by Solzhenitsyn's quick hand.
Yanov, again
using many references to Solzhenitsyn's texts, criticizes his obrazovanshchina
in some detail.
In attentively
reading obrazovanshchina, it is simply impossible not to notice
sentences such as; "a loss of
education is not life's most significant loss, and recommendations on how to
create a new "sacrificial elite," a new nucleus of people
"reared not so much on libraries, but on moral ordeals." It turns out that educational qualifications
and number of works published are entirely meaningless since we are reaching
the people along with "half literate advocates of religion."[98]
Yanov attempts
to reveal the reasons behind Solzhenitsyn's disdain for the intelligentsia and
for education. He finds them in
Solzhenitsyn's attempt to negate the existence of a contemporary Russian
intelligentsia, because it is oriented in a direction alien to russophiles---that
is, in the direction of Europeanization, anti-isolationism, and antimessianism.[99]
I share
Yanov's opinion regarding obrazovanshchina. But it occurs to me that this phenomenon may have a deeper
origin. Education is a very
contradictory process, especially if the education is focused on the natural
sciences to the detriment of the humanities and the social sciences. Actually, in this instance education may
promote the destruction of century-old values, as it fosters the opinion that
morality as an absolute value is meaningless, that all values are relative to
the current situation. And it must be
admitted that the natural sciences may foster the formation of undesirable
goals, having acquainted himself with great attainments in the spheres of
science and technology, pride may get the better of a person, and it may begin
to seem to him that everything is possible.
If a ruralist may create a utopia by calling for simplicity and
humility, then an obrazovanshchina may also create a utopia, only with
different features, that is, promising paradise on earth with an abundance of
goods and the unlimited subjugation of nature.
What's more,
an education is the natural sciences, particularly falling on primitive
philosophical soil, may promote the formation of quasi-primitive rationalism,
since it creates the illusion that everything can be rationally explained and
created. This type of illusion is the
best accomplice in creating a utopian paradise on earth based on strict
regulation. Here we already see a step
toward the authoritarian regime, which must embody such strict regulation; democracy cannot do this, because it is too
chaotic. And so Solzhenitsyn
unexpectedly closes with those he hated, the communists infected by the
West: the extremes have truly come
together!
Thus,
Solzhenitsyn is entirely consistent:
overidealization of the peasant, morality, and obrazovanshchina.
But the
opposite point of view can also be adopted;
that is, it can be demonstrated that education does not foster only the
creation of utopia. It is precisely a
high level of education in the natural sciences that leads to the understanding
that not everything is possible, that not only is a perpetual motion
machine impossible, but so is a social construction as similar to it as
communism is. (Just as a perpetual
motion machine presupposes the absence of hindering forces of friction, so
communism suggests that resources are unlimited and will not hamper the
creation of an abundance of everything that is needed.) It is precisely a high level of education
that enables one to understand the great idea of God, in the sense that one
understands that the most complex mechanisms reveal an order in the development
of the inorganic, the organic, and the social worlds, in counterbalance to the
oversimplified notions that at the basis of development are only arbitrary
changes (although the role of these should not be ignored either).
It is
precisely a high level of education that permits an understand of the enormous
role of morality as an institution of development an indeterminate world. We are indebted to the great wisdom of the
fathers of American democracy for the creation of a political system, a rarity
in its time, that is tolerant of different viewpoints and that provided a haven
to Solzhenitsyn. What would
Solzhenitsyn have done without a democratic society? Would he have died on a cross, another great martyr? They would not even have given him
this---they would have disposed of him on the sly, condemning him to anonymity
as authoritarian regimes have done time and time again with people no less
talented.
Solzhenitsyn's
psychological portrait also emerges from the citations used in the book to
analyze his political views.
The impression
is created that Solzhenitsyn considers himself a prophet who has come to return
Truth to the world. I have tried to
understand the origins of this belief, and have come to the conclusion that
they lie in his unusual fate.
Solzhenitsyn served as a military officer during World War II and came
out of it alive, when the majority of his fellow officers were killed; Solzhenitsyn endured Stalinist work camps
and remained alive and active, when many others did not survive the camps or
were broken by the experience; Solzhenitsyn
survived the cancer ward from whence very few emerge alive; Solzhenitsyn preserved much that he created
during these years, and, under conditions that were not conducive to
creativity, he produced new works that earned him fame not only in Russia but
the world over.
As a human
prophet who knows the Truth, Solzhenitsyn is intolerant of other views. This intolerance even sometimes leads to
conflicts with his own precepts, mainly with his rule that no person should
live according to lies. This may be too
sarcastic, but one well-know Soviet dissident noted rather aptly that, in Solzhenitsyn's
address, he calls for people not to live according to lies but with rights and
also with restrictions.)
I think that
Yanov is correct in accusing Solzhenitsyn of not following his own
precepts. Solzhenitsyn claims that, to
Yanov, "everything Russian is hateful," and that Yanov "is
published only in Young Communist and other even more trivial
publications."[100]
I have know Yanov for more that twenty year. Only rarely does one meet a greater patriot of Russia; he is a person who is deeply devoted to
Russia's interests and who wishes her success.
Yanov certainly considers himself a Russian person, if Russianness is
determined not by gene but by participation in the nation's culture (in the
broadest sense of the word.) To me, and
I feel that I am a follower of Judaism to a large degree (I mean, of course, in
the sense that it is common to all mankind), these characteristics are
particularly palpable. Yanov was not an
insignificant journalist in the U.S.S.R.
He has been published in the central press, particularly in the Literary
Gazette. One of the articles he had
published in this newspaper, "On the Roads of Smolenshchina," which
expresses the pain of central Russia's depopulation, brought him to light as
one of the leading Soviet journalists, one of those who are able to express the
poignant problems of the country's development in spite of press
censorship. Yanov has been published in
New World, a journal that brought Solzhenitsyn fame. And by the way, as far as I know, Yanov has
only published one article in Young Communist. But is was an unusual article, which enthusiastically circulated
from person to person. The article was
dedicated to the great Russian political figure Aleksander Herzen. Residing in the West, Herzen was not afraid to
express his disapproval of Russia's suppression of the insurrection in Poland.
The reader may
inquire in bewilderment: "Is it
really so courageous to speak out against Russia while living in the
West?" Yes, this was incredibly
courageous of Herzen, because Russia's imperialist action was widely supported
by Russian society. The Russian public
considered the great Russian patriot Herzen's statement antipatriotic. Far away from one's homeland, having given
it all your service, one must possess considerable bravery to be rejected bot
only by its leaders but by the public as well.
I think that
Alexander Yanov also has courage, having thrown down a challenge to the great
Russian writer, who does not share the democratic ideals of Russia. Here is how Yanov himself writes about it:
For the people
of Russia (myself included) Solzhenitsyn was (and for many still is) the
nation's conscience, a symbol of that of which we ourselves are not
capable. The point here not only
concerns artistic talent or legendary courage, the point also lies in the role
Solzhenitsyn has played in the spiritual emancipation of the country, and in my
own emancipation. The tragedy consists
in this person turning up in the ranks of "the new Russian
right." I am not saying that this
fact itself is indicative of the enormous power the tradition of the right has
in Russian culture. . . I want the
reader to understand clearly my outlook on Solzhenitsyn. It is embodied in the following
question: Why has this person who has
done so much for me later betrayed me?
And not only betrayed me, but cursed me along with the Russian
intelligentsia which he curses?[101]
I will risk a
reply to Yanov's last question. It
seems to me that Solzhenitsyn has not betrayed Yanov. As a critic of communism, of the godless tyrant Stalin,
Solzhenitsyn was perceived by liberal-minded people as their ally. But criticism of communism and Stalin can of
course come from the opposite position, from the position of fundamentalism,
which had begun to be observed early in Solzhenitsyn's works.
As the African saying goes, "if a
crocodile eats your enemy, it does not mean that he is your friend." In general, one should not create idols!
References
10
General Observations on Soviet Economic
Mechanism
In my analysis
of the Soviet economy I intend to adopt a general systems approach. It will be
recalled that a system can be analyze from multilateral perspective.[102] Generally speaking, among the many
facets of the system are the function (in the name of what); the institutions
between the function and the necessary ingredients (including energy and
information) - structure; the transformation of primary ingredients into final
product - process; the tools used to implement the process - operator; and the
impact of the system's prehistory on all the aspects mentioned above- genesis.
In principle, all these aspects are independent variables. This means that if
one aspect is fixed others still maintain a certain degree of freedom. Systems
vision consists of multifaceted analysis. Unnecessary arguments among scholars
in the same field frequently arise as a result of the system being narrowly
viewed from a single perspective.
Function, Structure, and General Properties of Soviet Economic
Mechanisms
The economic
system created under Stalin and, in principle, remaining to the present day,
was functionally oriented toward the country's expansionist development.
The economic system's structure and operating mechanism have been formulated
for this purpose. The pervasive impact of militarization on Soviet economy is
described in chapter 5.
The economic
system designed to fulfill this function exhibits an amazing mixture of
economic structures of various types.
To use Marxist terminology, these structures
correspond to economic formations. The top layer of Soviet bureaucrats lead a
life that is nearly communist, what with its declared principle "from each
according to his abilities, to each according to his needs." Most Soviet
urban dwellers live in a quasi socialist universe, otherwise known as the
system of state capitalism, which combines the socialist principles of
planning, job security, and pay equality with such capitalist institutions as
the labor and consumer goods markets. But the Soviet economic system also had
aspects of state feudalism, with all sorts of coercive supraeconomic devices to
limit the freedom of workers: in 1940, for example, the workers' freedom to
change jobs was sharply curtailed. In agriculture, "state feudalism"
was introduced with the creation of the collective farms, the kolkhozes.
In construction, especially in remote areas, "state slavery" was
preponderant in the form of labor camps. Here, it seems, Stalin acquired two
new sources of mass slavery: his own prisoners of war and supposedly serious
criminals, that is, those condemned for minor offenses to inordinately long
sentences.[103]
This analysis
of the Soviet economic structure is strictly at odds with a traditional Marxist
approach.
According to
the accepted Marxist socioeconomic doctrine, a consistent shift of formations
takes place. Each of these formations has its characteristic economic
structure. For example, corv'ee is a structure characteristic of feudal
society. It is therefore awkward, from the Marxist standpoint, to discuss the
fact that an essentially feudal structure functions in the socialist epoch.
But structural
formations in society arise because a specific mode of functioning generally
corresponds to the existing conditions. Analyzing the development of
socioeconomic systems from the standpoint of goals and the conditions of their
development, it is possible to see how in every concrete historical situation
a synthesis of the various structures occurs. These structures can appear or
disappear, depending on how social goals and conditions change. From this point
of view, one can say the following: In conditions when an extraordinary task
comes to the fore, when important resources are scarce, and when the level of
development is low, it might be expedient to use such management mechanisms as
slavery and serfdom. If the private economy remains, the worker can either
refuse to hand over the article that he has produced or he can produce less.
Although we shall not dwell at length on the conditions that demand slavery or corv'ee,
we can note the specific advantages of the corv'ee and quitrent systems.
Under the quitrent system, the laborer owns his own product and turns over a
part of that product, in one form or another, to the lord. On the other hand,
under corv'ee, the laborer must carry out direct obligations; the
product of his activity clearly does not belong to him. Moreover, it is easier
to pressure the serf into fulfilling obligations on the lord's estate than it
is to seize the product of the serf's labor. The corv'ee system provides
that a small allotment of land will be left to the laborer in order to keep him
alive. Therefore, one cannot generalize to a claim that quitrent is more
effective than corv'ee. Everything depends on the conditions underlying
the two structures.
One may assume
that under the conditions created in the 1930s, the introduction of corv'ee in
the form of kolkhoz production was one of the most convenient means of
confiscating agricultural output in order to carry out a policy of rapid
industrialization. (An entirely separate question, however, is whether such
rates of industrialization were necessary).
As far as the
slave structure is concerned, it too can be used in the Soviet Union. Through
the use of the labor-camp system, an enormous project of opening up new
regions was undertaken. If the regime were to implement these projects in a
capitalist fashion, it would have to incur considerable costs to encourage the
workers to move to remote areas, and to make these areas truly comfortable to
live in. If adequate resources are lacking, it is much cheaper to forcibly
relocate the workers to the newly developing regions, and create the conditions
there that are just barely sufficient for their short-term survival. High
mortality rates among the conscripted workers can be easily offset by new
cohorts of similarly relocated personnel.
To sum up, we
can say that each country forms its economic system as a synthesis of all the
possible economic structures taken in various proportions.
Now let us
move to the main subject of this chapter and see how the Soviet economy
functions in practice.
Every economic
system encounters a variety of conditions reflecting the availability of
natural resources, technology, culture, worker qualifications, level of mass
production, and so forth. Given this variety of conditions, the operation of an
economic system can be organized according to either of the two extreme
principles: the unification of all conditions and the subsequent creation of an
appropriate, unified mechanism, or the formation of a variety of mechanisms
corresponding to the variety of conditions. It is also possible to create one
type of mechanism to suit all different conditions. It is very difficult for a
bureaucracy to deal with a variety of conditions and mechanisms. Therefore, one
finds that the desire to unify conditions and mechanisms is typical of
bureaucratic management systems. One readily sees that in the Soviet Union
there is a tendency towards unification. The communist ideology facilitates
aspirations along this line by asserting that all complexity in the management
of economic systems is temporary, that is, typical only of the transitional
period from capitalism to socialism and from socialism to communism. The ideal
for the communist is a society in which everything will be organized in a
simple way, because all of the needs of the people will be satisfied and the
system of production will be directly oriented towards the satisfaction of
these needs.
Because the
modern economic system is so complex, Soviet leaders must pay attention to the
variety of conditions and to the efficiency of various mechanisms. At the
present time this variety is formed randomly rather than on the basis of a
sound economic theory. As a result, one sees many inconsistencies in the actions
of the participants in the Soviet economic system.
What is needed
is a sophisticated theory that ordains not only the ways of constructing
individual economic mechanisms - planned or market-type - but also a method of
synthesizing them.
The Soviet Planning System
The Soviet
economy rests on total planning. I do not wish to contribute to an abstract
discussion as to whether planning is good or bad in general. My purpose here is
only to pinpoint some negative aspects of planning, which I think are important
and about which I believe I can say something new.
Planning
Technological Progress
Soviet
economic theory contains no clear-cut notions about how to organize the
production and implementation of new technological and scientific ideas. The
Soviet centrally planned economy has been incapable of intensive growth based
on technological advances. This system was best, above all, for accomplishing
the extraordinary tasks of quickly creating a military potential with the help
of largely existing technologies, that is, for extensive growth in pursuit of
one clearly limited goal.
Because of a
monolithic ideology and a single source of financing for science, it is
difficult to expect the emergence of pioneering ideas, even if there is enough
broad cultural tolerance for upstarts who challenge the scientific
establishment. It is no surprise that the ratio of Nobel Prize winners to the
total number of scientists in the Soviet Union is so pathetically small. Even
if pioneering ideas appear first in the West, they may go begging in the
U.S.S.R. for a long time. This is true not only of the hoary cybernetics and
genetics, but also of such fairly recent revolutionary breakthroughs as the
tectonic theory in geology. New scientific ideas get taken up only when they
show a significant operational potential of a military nature. Then and only
then does the Soviet military intervene and insist that there is an urgent need
to finance the innovation. I do not know of a single new scientific idea of any
real importance - whether born in the West or homegrown - that was given a
green light without powerful prodding by the military. It is the military men
who can champion the new because they are responsible for the armed might of
the country - a matter of utmost import for the leaders, second only to their
own political survival.
Technological
innovation through the plan also encounters great complexities. Under
centralized planning the head of an enterprise is evaluated based on plan
fulfillment. It is extremely difficult to determine whose fault it is if a
production plan goes unfulfilled: if the plan assumes the introduction of a new
technology, it could be the boss's fault, but it could also be due to glitches
in the new equipment. Planning for familiar equipment is another matter; here,
it is easier to fulfill the plan and to fix blame in case of failure. I think
that the closeness of the relationship between Soviet leaders and those who
create new military hardware is also conditioned by the leaders' desire to have
reliable people they can trust to advise them on the reasons for possible
mishaps in creating the new. But is it possible for the leaders of a country to
be close to all the creators of the new?
Hierarchical
economic systems, generally speaking, are most efficient in situations where
the goal is reasonably clear, and where what is needed is for the center to
concentrate resources for the most promising projects, and to coordinate the
efforts of the participants. But in the field of R and D there is a need for parallel
and independent research and design organizations.
It cannot be overemphasized that parallelism
in the field of R and D is not an accidental phenomenon, but one one that
inheres in the very nature of uncertain processes. Even when the probable
calculations of costs and benefits are theoretically possible, it might make
sense to pursue several alternatives simultaneously until it becomes clear
which one is more advantageous. I base my conclusions on a pretty elaborate
class of mathematical models generally known as "multiproject bandit
processes."[104] The need for parallelism is still more
apparent in basic R and D, when we may not have even a probabilistic knowledge
of costs and benefits, and have to rely instead only on the known
predispositions of different scholars to one or another type of research.
Commonly,
economists view parallelism as a guarantee of efficient competition. They are
right: in certain situations, competition can be a sufficient condition for
parallel efforts. But even when it is not, it may still be wise to follow a
multitrack policy because of the lack of information, and vice versa.
Being aware of
both causes of parallelism is alone sufficient to improve even an essentially
centralized economy. But the next decisive step on the road to progress has to
await the appearance of decentralization and a multiplicity of independent
economic actors personally responsible for their actions.
Within the
framework of hierarchical mechanisms, parallel research is usually dubbed duplication
of effort. In this context the term acquires a negative meaning: one of the
main functions of the Committee on Science and Technology, which manages
science in the Soviet Union, is to "fight against duplication." I am
not saying that duplication is good in all cases, but in the area of R and D
the absence of parallel organizations presents far greater dangers.
Parallel
research could might be organized within the framework of a hierarchical
mechanism. But the experience of the U.S.S.R. and Germany during Hitler's time
shows that parallel investigation under a hierarchical mechanism is a very rare
phenomenon. It takes place primarily in the design of military technology. At
the same time, such organized parallelism also has some serious disadvantages
because it is accompanied by a system of appointments.
Hierarchical
mechanisms in R and D are particularly dangerous in totalitarian countries. In
these countries, the concept of a leader (führer) for the system as a whole is
duplicated in all other areas as well. That is why hierarchical mechanisms have
a tough leader whose authority is indisputable.[105]
Long-Range
Planning
A glaring gap
in the Soviet planning system is in the area of long-range planning.
In the
U.S.S.R. one could see only a single attempt to put together a realistic
long-range economic outline by Stalin in his speech in 1946. His proposal
mentioned only the goal, that is, the output of a certain volume of basic
products (steel, pig iron, oil, coal) during the next ten to fifteen years. I
do not know of a plan (or a program) that tried to show a way how to achieve
this goal. The well-known Soviet twenty-year plan for 1961-1980 was announced
by Nikita Khrushchev as the new program of the Communist party of the U.S.S.R.
This plan was a sheer political hoax. Its promise to build communism in 1980
was a bad joke.
In the
beginning of the 1970s another attempt was made to prepare a twenty year plan
for 1971-1990. This plan was to replace the party program, which had proved a
total fiasco. After Khrushchev, the leaders became more cautious. They asked
both the State Planning Committee and the Academy of Sciences of the U.S.S.R.
to prepare an outline of this plan. To the best of my knowledge, according to
the preliminary report prepared by the Academy of Sciences, the Soviet Union
would be unable to reach the level of output of the US by the year 1990; that
is, after seventy-three years of socialist revolution the country with the most
progressive socialist economic system cannot reach the level of output of a
country based on an obsolete capitalist system.
From this
standpoint, it is interesting to note an important feature of Soviet long-range
plans. If a plan is announced for one year or five years it is possible to
utter in the plan's preamble some meaningless words to the effect that the plan
is geared towards a further improvement in the standard of living of the Soviet
people, and so forth. In a plan of greater scope, it is necessary to specify
the qualitative changes that the plan will bring; these changes have to conform
to the greater advantages that the propaganda claims a socialist economy has
over a capitalist one. Here a conflict arises in the Soviet society: whether to
sacrifice the realism of the plan in the name of the ideology, or to stop any
preparation of long-range plans in the name of that same ideology. In the
U.S.S.R. it is impossible to develop a realistic long-range plan that could
satisfy the ideological requirements: the system is too inefficient.
One could
argue that the Soviets could develop a classified long-range plan. To the best
of my knowledge, the U.S.S.R. does not have such a plan. It seems to me that
the major reason for the absence of these plans lies in the overall structure
of the Soviet system and of its planning mechanism in particular. Concentration
of short-, mid-, and long-range planning in one organization guarantees that
the first two will be given priority over the last; the chief of the
organization simply does not have the time to think of long-range problems.
I myself had
an opportunity to verify these observations when, many years ago, I tried to
get the U.S.S.R. Gosplan interested in the implementation of the ideas of
optimal planning. The main objection I ran into was that, due to severe time
constraints, Gosplan had to concentrate on current and five-year plans. It is
characteristic of these plans that they demand special attention to the issues
of technological feasibility and input-output balancing. This approach by the
planners is largely determined by the rigidity of the plan. Even in a five-year
plan, approximately 80 percent of capital investments is determined by
unfinished construction begun during the previous years. Only 20 percent of
investment can be varied. In reality, however, a considerable portion of this
sum is also determined by the past because it is necessary to have blueprints
to start the construction; the preparation of these blueprints takes several
years. The portion of expenses allocated for the preparation of blueprints for
new plants is relatively small compared to the total amount of investment. If
that is the case, does it really make much sense to bother about an optimal
allocation of resources? Wouldn't it better to focus on balancing the bulk of
resources within the framework of five-year plans?
In other
words, rational utilization of resources within a limited period of time (for
example, five years) requires, first of all, that the outputs that are
predetermined by the past (unfinished construction and existing blueprints) be
balanced. The managers are aware of the concept of the existing mechanism of
planning performance. This helps them to be more ingenious in balancing
inputs-outputs. The elaboration of new concepts, which opens up new avenues in
selecting new projects, is quite foreign to the practitioners: they do not have
the time to do it. For selection they use old fashioned methods like
extrapolation, segmented political insights, and so on. But in the long-run,
that is, from the standpoint of long-range development, decisions regarding new
projects determine the efficiency of the economic system. In particular, these
decisions determine the possibilities of new projects to be undertaken in the
next five-year plan; this, in turn, determines the flow of construction in the
next period, and the cycle continues.
Soon after
Khrushchev came to power, he split up the State Planning Committee - Gosplan -
and organized the State Economic Council--Goseconomsovet along with it. The job
of this council was to develop long- and mid-range plans; Gosplan was to
concentrate on one- and two-year plans. But after a couple years these two
organizations were reunited. To the best of my understanding, the reason for
this merger was the following: generally speaking, in a totalitarian system all
spheres of society are controlled by the leaders. Especially in large
countries, the leaders do not have the time to seriously discuss long-range
problems because they have to spend most of their time on current issues.
Naturally, there were frictions between Gosplan and Goseconomsovet. The members
of the Politburo had no time to resolve conflicts between these two
organizations.[106]
Let me repeat
again that in this book I do not touch upon many other shortcomings of Soviet
planning. Very briefly, one such shortcoming has to do with deliberate
imbalances in the plan between supply and demand, when the former consistently
lags behind the latter. The interested reader can find a fascinating treatment
of this problem in the works of the Hungarian economist Janosh Kornai.[107]
Anomalies in the Soviet Hierarchical
Economic mechanism
Another set of
problems in the Soviet economy concerns the processes of plan formulation and
implementation.
Planning in
physical terms predominates in Soviet hierarchical-type economic mechanisms, in
which the role of the price mechanism is drastically reduced. An economic
system based on such a mechanism is appropriately called a command economy.
But the greater role of monetary parameters does not mean the introduction of a
market. It only means that the participants have more independence in their
internal activities because they are faced with less rigid external
constraints. Here, it is important to draw a sharp distinction between the
notions of deconcentration and decentralization. Decentralization
refers to horizontal interactions (excluding, of course, the centralized ones).
Deconcentration stands for greater flexibility within the set of vertical
interactions.[108]
Concentration
is at least a three-dimensional notion of breadth, depth, and length. By the
breadth of concentration I mean the number of external parameters pertaining to
the economic unit and controlled by a center. By the length of concentration I
mean the number of levels in the hierarchy controlled by a center. At different
levels the breadth of concentration may be different. By the depth of
concentration I mean the extent of intervention by the center in the internal
activities of the controlled unit.
The Soviet
economic system exhibits an excessive degree of concentration along each of these
three axes: enterprises are overburdened by the number of centrally-determined
controlling parameters; upper levels of the hierarchy penetrate deep within
individual enterprises, even down to the level of setting the wage schedule for
their workers; upper echelons largely control the internal activities of
subordinate organizations, including their system of appointments and
management structure.
All these
issues were hotly debated, but never resolved, when a major package of economic
reforms was proposed in 1965. The emphasis then was on deconcentration, whereas
today, under Gorbachev's perestroika, it has shifted to decentralization, that
is, to the market.
It is well known that a hierarchical system
assumes some common and specific features at different levels of the hierarchy.
Mistakes made in forming this hierarchically organized mechanism in the Soviet
Union could be understood, first of all, as a result of the fact that
isomorphic processes of management common to all levels were carried out in different
ways. This will become more clear if we examine the nature of these mistakes.
They are (1) a violation of the hierarchical principle in setting price, and
(2) a lack of coordination in aggregate parameters, both in real and in
monetary terms.
In the Soviet
Union the hierarchical principle of planning input-output in physical terms is
fairly systematic, that is, the higher level of the hierarchy hands down a plan
to the participants at the next lower level of the hierarchy. However, if one
examines the planning of prices, a completely different picture emerges. A
central planning agency - in this case the State Committee on Prices - skips
many levels and directly sets prices on all products produced by the factories.
The factory's planning department sometimes sets prices on all products
produced at the level of workshops, thereby violating the hierarchical
principle of planning.
I also want to
remind the reader that prices are not flexible because they are set for long
periods of time.
Price as an
economic phenomenon is used only in the interactions between the factories. At
higher levels, for example, in the chief departments of the ministries, or in
the ministries themselves, interactions are perceived by the participants as a
part of state management. At levels of the hierarchy lower than the factory,
for example, workshops and sections, relations between the participants are
perceived as being purely technical. The view of the factory as a focal point
of the hierarchy is not unfounded. It arises from the fact that, as a rule, a
Soviet factory is defined as an enterprise delimited by a certain territory.
Superior levels of the hierarchy, chief departments and ministers, are located
far from the factory in the capital of the country or of the union republic.
The lowest levels, workshops and sections, are located inside the factory. The
physical separation of the factory makes exercising complete control over it
impossible; this contrasts with the highest and lowest levels of the hierarchy
where such control is possible. Central planners are forced to spend a lot of
time and resources setting prices on the commodities that are consumed within a
ministry. For example, in the Ministry of Chemical Industry approximately
one-third of all kinds of items (not to be confused with absolute volume of
production) are intermediate goods that are consumed within the framework of
the ministry. However, the State Committee on Prices sets prices on all of
these products.
As already
mentioned, prices of products consumed within the factory are set by the
factory. This method of price setting has its weaknesses. Generally speaking,
at the point of equilibrium the price of any one commodity has to be the same
for all consumers. Certain products that are consumed within one factory could
be produced by other factories and also consumed within them. In that case,
prices of the same commodity will be different in different factories. The
disadvantage of this is obvious: factories have no information that can help
them determine the economic efficiency of being self-sufficient with respect to
a particular product. I know of cases in which chief departments of ministries
tried to avoid such problems. For example, during the 1950s the Chief
Department for the Production of Motorcycles and Bicycles of the Ministry of
Automobiles and Tractors, introduced internal prices on all kinds of
instruments produced in the workshops of the factories subordinate to this head
department.
Let us now
consider another violation in hierarchical mechanisms, a violation that results
from lack of coordination in the aggregation of products in physical and
monetary terms. Planning in physical terms is associated with different degrees
of aggregation according to the level of the managerial hierarchy. The higher
the level the greater the degree to which consumed and produced goods are
presented in aggregate form. Disaggregation of aggregated inputs-outputs is
realized by contracts between factories. As matter of fact, the price mechanism
does not involve these processes of aggregation and disaggregation. The
Committee on Prices sets prices for all factories and for all the goods they
produce, even to the point, say, of setting prices for each variety of fishing
hooks.
During the
Soviet economic reform of the middle 1960s much attention was focused on
developing direct links (priamye sviazi) between enterprises. But in
many cases this process was rooted in the imperfections of the planning
mechanism based on the hierarchical line, and in the inability of this plan to
ensure proper conditions for direct interaction between the links. Let me
specify what I mean.
In devising
direct links it is necessary, above all, to fulfill certain material
prerequisites (materials, equipment, etc.) in the plan. This provides for a
certain flexibility among the participants. For example, in order to ensure
flexible relations between shops and factories manufacturing footwear, there
must be, at least in the factories, readily available means to convert from one
style of footwear to another. Considering that a particular type of footwear is
maintained for a long time, current alterations are merely a matter of changing
a few details, so the manufacturing technology does not have to be altered in
any major way. Given the technology of footwear manufacturing, it is necessary
above all to have the means to alter those parts of the shoe having the
greatest versatility. This versatility may be attained by using alterable metal
lasts. The existing process of shoe manufacturing utilized less versatile
wooden lasts. The capacity to manufacture these lasts was thereby limited.
Moreover, output was further reduced in connection with a partial switch by the
enterprises producing wooden lasts to the production of furniture necessitated
by an acute demand stemming from an expanding housing construction.
Incidentally, interactions at the same level
are guided by the principle "Money talks," which is termed in the
Soviet Union "Control by a Ruble" (kontrol' rublem). This
means that the activities of the factory are partially controlled by other
factories, which purchase its commodities. One does not see this type of
control in the Soviet Union at levels higher or lower than the factory.
Schizophrenic
Character of Soviet Economic Mechanism
I think that
the anomalies of the Soviet economy outlined above are generated primarily by
the disjunction between the monetary and physical aspects of the mechanism of
its functioning.
One of the
main reasons that the need for consistent planning at all levels of the
hierarchy is ignored lies in the fact that the Soviet economists do not
understand that prices are dual variables, which serve as a tool to help form
and implement the plan. Soviet economists, both in theory and in practice,
separate the process of planning in physical terms from the setting of prices.
They assume that the task of planning of input-output in physical terms must
balance supply and demand. They conceive of prices as mere production costs,
which should be calculated on the basis of the labor theory of value. Because
it is impossible to avoid prices in the course of planning in physical terms,
the use of the wrong prices could lead to a great waste of resources in the
national economy. For example, planning in physical terms is based on the range
of technologies offered by the design bureau. However, in developing these
technologies design bureaus are guided by obsolete prices, which they use to
avoid economically ineffective solutions.
At the same
time, in the Soviet economic system there are managers endowed with common
sense. These people usually have enough common sense to set logically
formulated goals (the nature of these goals from the standpoint of humaneness,
for example, is another matter). Meanwhile, their common sense is not sufficient
to formulate a relatively effective, internally unified mechanism of
performance; they have created instead a disjunct, schizophrenic mechanism.
The common
sense of these people is sometimes enough to avoid the absurdities engendered
by the disparity between the goals set and the schizophrenic mechanism for
their attainment. Sometimes they, or at least their subordinates, become the
victims of the mechanism they themselves have created. The following examples,
somewhat sketchy but based on facts taken from Soviet practice, can serve to
illustrate this point (the figures cited are arbitrary).
The first
example bears out the adequacy of common sense to combat schizophrenia with
sensibly formulated goals. In the U.S.S.R. at one time there arose an urgent
need to increase the production of plastic parts for bombs, a kind of item very
important to the country.
The government instructed one of the plastic
plants to increase production by approximately one-and-a-half times in a very
short period. It was impossible to meet this target using an extensive approach
- by expanding production capacities through the installation of additional
presses - because this would require time: the plant would have had to construct
new production buildings, order additional equipment, and wait for the new
equipment to be manufactured. The realization of the target might have been
drawn out for several years.
The plant's
engineers took another course that enabled them to meet the target in a very
short time. They recognized that pressing was the limiting link in the
production of plastics. The initial temperature of the molding powder
significantly influences the length of this process. For this reason, the
engineers decided to install high-frequency current generators near the
presses, use them to preheat the powder, and thus raise the productivity of the
presses. And indeed, press productivity was essentially increased and
production rose to the projected level. The management and engineering
personnel of the enterprise had successfully coped with the important task and
were awarded the State Prize.
But when the
plant's economic indicators were analyzed, it was found to be deep in the hole.
First, output per press operator had declined. Under the previous, longer
pressing cycle, one operator tended two presses; but under the new conditions,
with the shorter period of pressing, a press operator was unable to serve two
units, and additional labor had to be hired. Since the number of press
operators doubled while the productivity of the presses increased only
one-and-a-half times, output per operator fell.
Second, the
cost of production increased, since the wages of a press operator remained the
same although the output per operator dropped. The wage level remained
unchanged because the intensity of the operator's labor was not decreased,
since additional operations involved in heating the molding powder had to be
performed. The cost of production was also increased by the increase in
expenditures per item on electric power: expenditures had to be made on
technological power for preheating the molding powder. Even though overall
output at the plant expanded, the reduction of the overhead per item could not
compensate for the increase in these expenditures.
The transfer
prices remained the same. According to the established principles, the prices
reflected average costs across all plants producing similar items, plus a small
profit. While the given enterprise cost of production increased appreciably,
the plant started operating at a loss, with all the ensuing negative
consequences (for example, absence of the managers' fund). The other plants,
which stuck with the old technology, continued to operate in the black.
Thus a single
measure received two different assessments: the plant had to be simultaneously
pardoned and executed.
The overall
economic mechanism of functioning created by the government demanded that the
plant be "executed" - after all, the plant had begun operating at a
loss. At an important conference organized in the course of a government
campaign to improve the economic indicators of enterprises, I myself witnessed
a tongue-lashing administered to the management of a plastics plant by district
party authorities for poor economic performance.
Naturally, if
the regular principles of supply and demand were brought to bear on the
situation, the enterprise that managed to increase rapidly the output of an
important commodity would not only have registered no loss, but would have
instead shown a profit.
Common sense, however,
does not always win out. Sometimes, Soviet leaders become the victims of the
illogicality of the very system they have fathered.
In the
mid-1960s, the country was overstocked with expensive suits. Under such
circumstances one would expect a clearance sale of the product that has already
been manufactured. In addition, production of the unmarketable goods would be
curtailed. Contractual relationships between shops and enterprises were
employed in an attempt to determine the best assortment for the items to be put
on the market. However, even with the means for expanding the manufacturing of
less expensive suits being available at the clothing factories, it turned out
to be fairly difficult to implement in actual practise. Like in a famous
parable of a camel created by a congressional committee, the monetary reference
points used in the Soviet economic system and those for which the workers stand
tend, for a variety of reasons, to gravitate in different directions. There is
no clear-cut way to coordinate the efforts of these people. Let me clarify this
point.
It is known
that in the U.S.S.R. the most important monetary reference point for the
leaders are the growth rates of industrial output. These rates are measured by
the gross output (in fixed prices) of the respective industry. This indicator
has also an important ideological significance in showing the advantages of a
planned system. If we recall that, other thing being equal, the greater the
cost of component materials, the higher the price of the product, it follows
that a decline in the production of expensive suits results in a reduction in
gross industrial output. The top workers of Gosplan who were responsible, above
all else, for attaining high growth rates in production, received this idea of
cutting down the output of expensive suits with disfavor.
Moreover, one
of the major sources of the U.S.S.R.'s budget revenues is the turnover tax
levied on consumer goods. In order to protect the financing of various state
budget needs from the possibly "irrational" behavior of consumers, a
turnover tax in the U.S.S.R. is collected at the point where commodities are
transferred from industry to wholesale trade, or from wholesale to retail
trade. It is never collected at the stage of sale to the consumer. In the
U.S.S.R., the turnover tax on expensive commodities is often higher than on
inexpensive goods. From what has been said, it becomes clear that, if there is
a reduction in the output of expensive suits, there will also be a shortage in
the revenue part of the budget. Under these circumstances one should not expect
officials in the Ministry of Finance to support a decree calling for the
curtailment of the production of expensive suits.
The concern of
the Soviet banking system is that it has limited credit for unmarketable goods.
Moreover, the bank has a cash plan that depends on money proceeds from the
population. Under these conditions directors of the bank would applaud all
enactments intended to expand the production of such goods as inexpensive suits.
The most
important indicator of success in retail trade in the U.S.S.R. is fulfilling a
plan for selling the commodity. Trade workers, therefore, would naturally be
interested in escalating the production of inexpensive suits. Moreover, the
availability of marketable goods reduces the retail sale storage problem .
Thus, on the
one hand, decreasing the production of expensive suits could weaken the significance of such an
important indicator as the growth rate of gross industrial output, and it could
reduce the revenues in the budget. On the other hand, it would be likely to
improve the cash plan and reduce unwanted inventories in the shops. More
important, the population would be protected.
What are the
country's leaders to do under these circumstances? In a story lamenting an
excess inventory of expensive suits, one national newspaper urged that their
manufacture be terminated, but, it added, without damaging the interests of the
state. In reality, this meant that the factors of output growth and budget revenue
had won out.
Since Soviet retail organizations have a
legal right to refuse unmarketable goods supplied under contract by a
distributor, it may seem that the situation could have been resolved
peacefully, without administrative interference. In fact, however, these
contracts can be ignored. As long as the manufacturer keeps his promise to
produce certain goods, the retail organization has to accept them. If it
refuses, the supplier won't have the money to pay its workers' wages. The party
functionaries, fearing a political bombshell, would come hard upon the
recalcitrant retailer and force him to take the merchandise.
Roots of Schizophrenia in Soviet Economic Mechanism
Every economic system wants to have adequate
and precise information about its significant economic parameters. But in
practice the following dilemma arises: whether to derive approximate figures on
the basis of an elaborate concept or to calculate exact figures on the basis of
a less-developed concept. The approximate figures are estimated on the basis of
intuition by people involved in economic activities; the exact figures can be
obtained by formalized procedures and eventually by computers.
What is
attractive in a market mechanism is its informal character in general.
Meanwhile, it is assumed that each participant has the ability to measure the
magnitude of economic parameters in the course of interactions. At the same
time, the disadvantages of a market mechanism, for instance, the imperfect
coordination of activities, manifest themselves in the inexactness of the
measurements of these parameters. Here, the problem of improving upon these
methods of measurement arises. One way to solve the problem is to create a
mechanism of centralized planning on the basis of a nationalized economy, but
this is an extreme approach. Such methods are typical of Marxists and, as with
any radical view, they are important in developing new avenues of thought.
Meanwhile, this approach is rather limited, for it ignores the diversity of
mechanisms vital to the performance of a developed economic system.[109]
The
simplification of economic reality seen in radical views is also a result of
the assumption that economic parameters are easy to measure. Marx and Engels
believed that, in the communist society of the future, it would be a simple
matter to measure both the desires of people and the resources needed to
fulfill these desires.
When Marxist
ideas of creating a new society began to be implemented in the U.S.S.R., the
first step was to form a rigid, centralized economy with all resources
distributed by the center -- down to the final bolt. Such methods were called
"War Communism" and were practiced during the period of the Russian
Civil War. At that time the goal of production was clear, and the variety and scope
of outputs were tremendously reduced. Toward the end of the 1920s the U.S.S.R.
began to develop into a modern industrial society, using centralized planning
mechanisms. Immediately the problem of setting goals for mid-term plans arose.
When Soviet leaders had to set these goals in the realm of consumer goods and
services, they faced a number of problems resulting from the lack of a
developed concept of how to measure the utility of different consumer goods and
services. Fortunately for the Soviet leaders, the goals of the system were
oriented toward military needs. This allowed the leaders to avoid the
complicated issue of measuring the utility of consumer goods and services.
Instead, this problem was replaced by a relatively simpler problem concerned with
the production of basic capital goods: oil, steel, electricity, tractors, and
so forth. Production of consumer goods and services was regarded as a
"boring" constraint.
The Soviet
planners also avoided the important problem of measuring cost-benefit at the
macrolevel, and instead focused their effort on balancing in physical terms the
output of basic goods with the inputs of necessary resources. I do not want to
play down the role of cost-benefit analysis at the macrolevel (for instance,
planners need for measuring the rate of growth), but these problems were of
secondary importance compared to the more vital problem of increasing the
output of basic capital goods.
Cost-benefit
analysis was explicitly formulated at the microlevel. Engineers whose task is
to select the best technologies and managers who measure deviations from the
planned inputs-outputs have to know how to compare costs and benefits. To do
this a price system must be elaborated. But Soviet economists did not know how
to set prices in a planned economy. They were faced with the following dilemma:
either to set prices on the basis of the Marxist labor theory of value, or on
the basis of the theory of marginal utility. This dilemma gave rise to many
ideological controversies. Marx and Engels rejected the price mechanism under
socialism altogether. However, they thought that, under capitalism, prices
gravitate towards average cost and orbit around it depending on demand and
supply at each moment of time. In 1940, Stalin, acting on Lev A. Leontiev's
advice, stated at a meeting with a group of Soviet economists that the
"law of labor value" was operating in the Soviet economy, but in a
modified form. I want to emphasize that adoption of the labor theory of value
as a tool for setting prices was not merely a bow to the Marxist ideology. I
think the viability of the concept of "labor value" and its
acceptance by the overwhelming majority of Soviet economists and politicians to
the present day is not simply lip service paid to the governing ideology, but
has deep roots. The labor theory of values seduces people by its simplicity, by
the illusion of the ease of measuring average labor spent at producing a
certain commodity. But measuring labor costs leads to a lot of problems, for
example, how to reduce skilled labor to unskilled labor, how to link the time
of production of a commodity with labor expenses, how to divide labor expenses
among indivisible goods, and so forth.
Of course one
could say that all these difficulties are to be expected since, every concept
has its unresolved problems. Moreover, if one examines the theory of marginal
utility, one is struck by the impracticality of measuring the utility of goods
having a different usage. Furthermore, how can one add shoes to butter from the
standpoint of their utility? It is a different matter when the common
denominator that determines the value of all different kinds of products is
labor expense! In this case everything seems clear and certain!
Thus, Soviet
planners chose average labor cost as the basis for setting prices. On the one
hand, these expenses are distinct from the utilities of the product, and on the
other hand, they do not take into account such things as the costs of natural
resources, the scarcity of the factors of production, or the time of
production. When Soviet planners try to direct the activities of the factories
via such prices, they create serious conflicts. In many cases it was impossible
to link the necessity of producing a certain item, even if that item was needed
for military purposes, with the costs of production. In principle, a Soviet
planner can adjust these prices to the prices of equilibrium, but this will
immediately give rise to a number of methodological problems: if the law of
labor value is used in a planned economy to set prices, then planned prices
should correspond exactly to the labor value. At the same time, one cannot vary
these prices around the labor value, because in the plan, supply and demand are
in equilibrium.
But
methodological puzzles were not the main obstacle in introducing a proper
pricing mechanism into the Soviet economy. If necessary, Soviet leaders could
easily adapt ideology and methodology to their interests; they do it under the
banner "the creative elaboration of Marxism." The major obstacle in
establishing a proper price mechanism is really the inability to implement the
market mechanism. Lack of a flexible economic mechanism, aggravated by disjoint
setting of prices and inputs-outputs in physical terms, has lead to a waste of
resources even in cases where Soviet planners have tried to set prices closer
to the product's marginal utility. For example, before World War II the Soviet
government sharply increased the price of copper. At that time there was a
great shortage of copper which was needed for military use. Higher price on
copper impelled engineers to reduce the usage of this material in different
kinds of electrical machines. As is often the case with a bureaucracy, it is
difficult to both introduce new prices and then change these prices under new
conditions. The higher price on copper was not changed for many years. This
led, for instance, to higher costs for electric motors, which then required
more electricity because less efficient materials were substituted for copper
in the motors.
Thus, the choice of the class of economic
mechanisms is, to a great extent, determined by the ability to make adequate
measurements of the processes taking place in the system. The temptation to use
planning mechanisms instead of market mechanisms is also based on the illusion
of being able to easily measure these processes. In turn, this illusion creates
another illusion: that the intuition of the people involved in a planning
mechanism can be replaced by formalized procedures.
In reality the
contrary is true: development of formalized procedures for managing the economy
is tremendously difficult and, if possible at all, can take a long time.
Attempts to go beyond the area where formalized measurements of economic
parameters do work leads to the formation of inefficient economic systems.
Alternative Scenarios for Improving the
Soviet Economic Mechanism
For a Soviet
liberal, the major challenge facing his country today is how to effect a
transition from a highly industrialized but politically authoritarian imperial
regime to a free society with a market-type economy. The present Soviet
leadership, it may be argued, wants to preserve an authoritarian imperial
regime, but through flexible means, including a market economy. In my opinion,
such a regime is not easily compatible with a market, if no other reason that
it induces excessive militarization and, as a result, a hypertrophied state
that acts as a sole monopsonistic buyer of weapons systems and intermediate
products.
A major
assumption that I make in discussing the various "optimistic"
scenarios is that the Soviet Union will shift to a peaceful economy, that is,
to an economy that in peacetime is geared toward the production of consumer
goods, and in which the defense burden does not reach the critical mass that
deforms the entire system (for details, see chapter 5). I further assume that
in time Soviet leaders may come to realize that, given the prevailing strategic
realities in the world, Russia alone cannot confront militarily all the
developed countries and an as-yet an undeveloped China. The Soviet leadership
may hence decide to enter the world community as an equal partner, and to rely
on international cooperation to increase the welfare of its own people rather
than attempting to subvert other nations through intimidation. Under these rosy
assumptions, it makes sense to ask how the Soviet Union may evolve a more
sophisticated mix of economic mechanisms. Otherwise, for a militarized economy,
it is difficult to argue against a rigidly hierarchical system whose planners
run everything from R and D to production and distribution.
In light of this, the views expressed by
Marshal Nikolaj Ogarkov during his tenure as first Deputy to the minister of
defense and chief of staff of the Soviet Army are of particular interest.
Because they represent an extreme method of solving domestic problems, based on
total militarization, I have below reproduced the full text of his suggestions
on the improvement of the centralized mechanism.
"In our
country during peacetime construction, as in other countries, a certain part of
the armed forces is on continuous alert, that is fully staffed with personnel
and military technology, and the remaining part is prepared for immediate
deployment. If the aggressor should unleash a conflict, personnel and technical
resources kept in reserve and assigned to specific units and battalions must
arrive to support them within an exceptionally short time frame. Because of
this, the issue of constant readiness for the immediate mobilization of
land-based troops and naval forces gains extreme governmental significance.
In earlier
wars, as we know, this issue was not as crucial. The element of surprise was
already playing a definite role in World War II. Now, it has become a factor of
strategic defense. The question of the timely transfer of the armed forces and
the entire national economy to a wartime posture, of their mobilization within
a brief time period, is now much more significant. Therefore, supplying the
troops with manpower and technical resources predetermines the necessity of
party members to plan precisely -- during peacetime -- the measures of
coordinated action between soviet and military organs.
Today as never
before, completely coordinated mobilization of the armed forces and the
national economy is absolutely essential, particularly the deployment of human
resources, transportation, communications, and power, in order to support the
stability and vitality of the country's economic mechanism. In connection with
this, continuous effort in the area of improving the industrial connections of
those enterprises that produce basic sorts of armaments is also necessary, as
is the autonomy of such industries in the case of a war. Such industries should
be completely supplied with energy and water resources as well as with other
vital resources from existing reserve equipment and materials. Further
improvements in the preparation of the national economy to mobilize itself are
necessary, because the close interdependence of the mobilization of the armed
forces, the national economy, and the civil defense mechanisms is the most
vital condition for the complete support of the country's defense capabilities
at the necessary level.
The
concentration of all efforts toward the attainment of the goals proposed,
taking into consideration the changing conditions of modern warfare and the
difficulty of mobilization, is impossible without a stable system of
centralized leadership of the country and of the armed forces. We do have a
certain amount of experience in this area. The creation during World War II of
the State Committee for Defense and the committee for the Defense of Cities
near the Front have been completely justified. It is only natural that we must
consider this experience. In future wars, if the imperialists don't engage us,
the role and significance of local party members, and of soviet and economic
organs in the solution of defense problems, will increase significantly."[110]
Marshal
Ogarkov's prescriptions remind us that there is no such thing as a universal,
ready-made economic system for each and every country, including Russia. There
are too many national idiosyncrasies, cultural and otherwise, for such a
universal scheme to be practicable. I do not believe in the convergency theory,
which implicitly holds out a promise of an ideal system, to be constructed out
of the best elements of the already existing ones. I do not deny, of course,
that there are convergent processes at work in the industrialized countries. I
only want to underscore that there are also some very important divergent
processes there that reflect a dissimilarity of national circumstances.
It is on a
possible integration of the common and the particular that I pin my theoretical
hopes. The concept of economic invariants (that is, universal economic
institutions relevant to all mechanisms) together with an analysis of
individual national circumstances, could serve as a theoretical foundation for
a systematic study of economic mechanisms. Among these invariants are relations
(for instance, coercion), organizations (such as mediators), and parameters
(for example, prices). Of course, the formation of these invariants is
accomplished differently in different mechanisms.
The majority
of Soviet scholars and practitioners do not understand the role of prices,
money, profit, competition, inflation, and so forth as invariants.
Unfortunately, some scholars in the Western countries are of the opinion that
all of these institutions are the exclusive prerogatives of Western market
economies. However, these institutions are economic invariants; that is, they
could be incorporated into any kind of economic mechanism. From this point of
view, what distinguishes different mechanisms are the processes by which these
invariants are introduced. In horizontal mechanisms, invariants are a direct
result of the interactions among the participants. In vertical mechanisms, they
result from actions taken at higher levels of the hierarchy. Failure to
understand that monetary parameters are actually invariants led to some false
ideological discussions. For example, the people who regard profit as a market
institution accuse the proponents of deconcentration of Soviet economic
mechanism of an attempt to revive capitalism in the Soviet Union. The
supporters of deconcentration are forced to spend a lot of time developing
ruses in order to prove that institutions of a Western market economy could
occasionally be used in the Soviet economy.
A synthesis of
the invariants and the particulars requires an open system, for in an uncertain
world it is in principle impossible to settle once and for all on the best
scheme. To avoid the lure of monism, we need a pluralistic mechanism of a kind
adumbrated in Chapter 2. The best guarantee of a successful long-term
development is a pluralistic mechanism, and not some enlightened and wise
ruler. It is this mechanism that offers a rich array of alternative economic
strategies, from which the nation, in a given situation, can choose a single
alternative or a combination of several. It is, lastly, a pluralistic mechanism
that enables the nation to monitor the progress of the selected alternative,
and to change the alternative if it proves inadequate either because of its own
faults or because of changed circumstances.
Now I would
like to put forward one economic strategy that I believe might be suitable for
the Soviet Union in a transitional period, while at the same time creating
preconditions for progress beyond the transitional stage.
For the
purpose of this discussion I divide all economic mechanisms into the vertical
and horizontal mechanisms.
This division
represents only a dichotomous expression of a possible spectrum of relations
between the participants from the standpoint of the degree to which one is
obligated to follow the instructions of the other. Verticality implies that the
instructions from one participant to another are of a compulsory nature;
horizontality assumes equality of the participants.
The presence
of vertical mechanisms is usually associated with the presence in the economic
system of an omnipotent government which coercively plans the activities of the
participants. In many cases, and especially in the Soviet-type economies,
government involvement in the economic system is linked with such vertical
mechanisms. However, one can imagine a government that merely regulates the
activities of the participants or even a government that could offer an
indicative plan.
Planning
mechanisms include methods of elaborating plans (that is, methods to elaborate
goals and to collect the necessary information regarding constraints), methods
of choosing between plans at any given time, and methods of stimulating
participants to follow the plan (which may range from rewards to participants
who follow the plan, to censure of those who fail to follow the plan, to the
physical annihilation of participants who do not fulfill the plan). In
principle, that one participant has more power than another does not mean that
the former must oppress the latter, that is, must obligate him to follow his
plans exactly. Strictly speaking, the idea of indicative planning, which
was used in Japan and some Western European countries, is an example of a
similar type of agreement between a state and its economic units.
In Soviet economic literature one can find
suggestions that the existing compulsory system of relations between different
levels of the managerial hierarchy, which is called planning, could be replaced
by contracts. However, the implementation of such recommendations is
impossible, if only because managers at a given level are reluctant to impose a
fine on their superiors, who have appointed them.
The market belongs to the class of horizontal mechanisms, which includes two other polar types of mechanisms different from the market. We shall call these centralized horizontal mechanisms and decentralized horizontal mechanisms of a nonmarket type. Centralized horizontal mechanisms are distinguished by the fact that the manager sets aggregate econom